For use at 11:00 a.m. EDT
July 5, 2019
Monetary Policy rePort
July 5, 2019
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Letter of transmittaL
B  G  
F R S
Washington, D.C., July 5, 2019
T P   S
T S   H  R
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report pursuant to
section 2B of the Federal Reserve Act.
Sincerely,
Jerome H. Powell, Chairman
Adopted effective January24, 2012; as amended effective January29, 2019
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is rmly committed to fullling its statutory
mandate from the Congress of promoting maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate
long-term interest rates. The Committee seeks to explain its monetary policy decisions to the public
as clearly as possible. Such clarity facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and
businesses, reduces economic and nancial uncertainty, increases the eectiveness of monetary
policy, and enhances transparency and accountability, which are essential in a democratic society.
Ination, employment, and long-term interest rates uctuate over time in response to economic and
nancial disturbances. Moreover, monetary policy actions tend to inuence economic activity and
prices with a lag. Therefore, the Committee’s policy decisions reect its longer-run goals, its medium-
term outlook, and its assessments of the balance of risks, including risks to the nancial system that
could impede the attainment of the Committee’s goals.
The ination rate over the longer run is primarily determined by monetary policy, and hence the
Committee has the ability to specify a longer-run goal for ination. The Committee rearms its
judgment that ination at the rate of 2percent, as measured by the annual change in the price
index for personal consumption expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the
Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate. The Committee would be concerned if ination were running
persistently above or below this objective. Communicating this symmetric ination goal clearly to the
public helps keep longer-term ination expectations rmly anchored, thereby fostering price stability
and moderate long-term interest rates and enhancing the Committee’s ability to promote maximum
employment in the face of signicant economic disturbances. The maximum level of employment
is largely determined by nonmonetary factors that aect the structure and dynamics of the labor
market.
These factors may change over time and may not be directly measurable. Consequently,
it would not be appropriate to specify a xed goal for employment; rather, the Committee’s policy
decisions must be informed by assessments of the maximum level of employment, recognizing that
such assessments are necessarily uncertain and subject to revision. The Committee considers a
wide range of indicators in making these assessments. Information about Committee participants’
estimates of the longer-run normal rates of output growth and unemployment is published four
times per year in the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections. For example, in the most
recent projections, the median of FOMC participants’ estimates of the longer-run normal rate of
unemployment was 4.4percent.
In setting monetary policy, the Committee seeks to mitigate deviations of ination from its
longer-run goal and deviations of employment from the Committee’s assessments of its maximum
level. These objectives are generally complementary. However, under circumstances in which the
Committee judges that the objectives are not complementary, it follows a balanced approach in
promoting them, taking into account the magnitude of the deviations and the potentially dierent
time horizons over which employment and ination are projected to return to levels judged
consistent with its mandate.
The Committee intends to rearm these principles and to make adjustments as appropriate at its
annual organizational meeting each January.
Statement on Longer-run goaLS and monetary PoLicy Strategy
Contents
note: This report reects information that was publicly available as of noon EDT on July2, 2019.
Unless otherwise stated, the time series in the gures extend through, for daily data, July1, 2019; for monthly data,
May2019; and, for quarterly data, 2019:Q1. In bar charts, except as noted, the change for a given period is measured to
its nal quarter from the nal quarter of the preceding period.
For gures 20 and 34, note that the S&P 500 Index and the Dow Jones Bank Index are products of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its afliates
and have been licensed for use by the Board. Copyright © 2019 S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, a division of S&P Global, and/or its afliates. All rights
reserved. Redistribution, reproduction, and/or photocopying in whole or in part are prohibited without written permission of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC.
For more information on any of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC’s indices please visit www.spdji.com. S&P® is a registered trademark of Standard & Poor’s
Financial Services LLC, and Dow Jones® is a registered trademark of Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC. Neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones
Trademark Holdings LLC, their afliates nor their third party licensors make any representation or warranty, express or implied, as to the ability of any
index to accurately represent the asset class or market sector that it purports to represent, and neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark
HoldingsLLC, their afliates nor their third party licensors shall have any liability for any errors, omissions, or interruptions of any index or the data
included therein.
Summary ................................................................. 1
Economic and Financial Developments ......................................... 1
Monetary Policy
........................................................... 2
Special Topics
............................................................. 3
Part 1: Recent Economic and Financial Developments ..................... 5
Domestic Developments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Financial Developments
.................................................... 20
International Developments
................................................. 26
Part 2: Monetary Policy ................................................. 33
Part 3
: Summary of Economic Projections ............................... 45
Abbreviations
...........................................................49
List of Boxes
How Have Lower-Educated Workers Fared since the Great Recession? .................. 8
Developments Related to Financial Stability
..................................... 24
The Persistent Slowdown in Global Trade and Manufacturing
........................ 30
Monetary Policy Rules and Their Interactions with the Economy
...................... 37
Framework for Monetary Policy Implementation and
Normalization of the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet
............................ 42
1
summary
Economic activity increased at a solid pace
in the early part of 2019, and the labor
market has continued to strengthen. However,
ination has been running below the Federal
Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) longer-
run objective of 2percent. At its meeting in
June, the FOMC judged that current and
prospective economic conditions called for
maintaining the target range for the federal
funds rate at 2¼ to 2½percent. Nonetheless,
in light of increased uncertainties around
the economic outlook and muted ination
pressures, the Committee indicated that it will
closely monitor the implications of incoming
information for the economic outlook and will
act as appropriate to sustain the expansion,
with a strong labor market and ination near
the Committee’s symmetric 2percent objective.
Economic and Financial
Developments
The labor market. The labor market has
continued to strengthen. Over the rst ve
months of 2019, payrolls increased an average
of 165,000 per month. This rate is down
from the average pace of 223,000 in 2018,
but it is faster than what is needed to provide
jobs for new entrants into the labor force.
The unemployment rate moved down from
3.9percent in December to 3.6percent in
May; meanwhile, wage gains have remained
moderate.
Ination. Consumer price ination, as
measured by the 12-month change in the price
index for personal consumption expenditures,
moved down from a little above the FOMC’s
objective of 2percent in the middle of last year
to a rate of 1.5percent in May. The 12-month
measure of ination that excludes food and
energy items (so-called core ination), which
historically has been a better indicator than the
overall gure of where ination will be in the
future, was 1.6percent in May—down from
a rate of 2percent from a year ago. However,
these year-over-year declines mainly reect
soft readings in the monthly price data earlier
this year, which appear to reect transitory
inuences. Survey-based measures of longer-
run ination expectations are little changed,
while market-based measures of ination
compensation have declined recently to levels
close to or below the low levels seen late
lastyear.
Economic growth. In the rst quarter, real gross
domestic product (GDP) is reported to have
increased at an annual rate of 3.1percent,
bolstered by a sizable contribution from net
exports and business inventories. By contrast,
consumer spending in the rst quarter was
lackluster but appears to have picked up in
recent months. Meanwhile, following robust
gains last year, business xed investment
slowed in the rst quarter, and indicators
suggest that investment decelerated further
in the spring. All told, incoming data for the
second quarter suggest a moderation in GDP
growth—despite a pickup in consumption—
as the contributions from net exports and
inventories reverse and the impetus from
business investment wanes further.
Financial conditions. Nominal Treasury yields
moved signicantly lower over the rst half
of 2019, largely reecting investors’ concerns
about trade tensions and the global economic
outlook, as well as expectations of a more
accommodative path for the federal funds
rate than had been anticipated earlier. On net,
since the end of 2018, spreads of yields on
corporate bonds over those on comparable-
maturity Treasury securities have narrowed,
and stock prices have increased. Moreover,
loans remained widely available for most
households, and credit provided by commercial
banks continued to expand at a moderate
pace. Overall, domestic nancial conditions
for businesses and households continued to be
supportive of economic growth over the rst
half of 2019.
2 SUMMARY
Financial stability. The U.S. nancial system
continues to be substantially more resilient
than in the period leading up to the nancial
crisis. Asset valuations remain somewhat
elevated in a number of markets, with
investors continuing to exhibit high appetite
for risk. Borrowing by businesses continues to
outpace GDP, with the most rapid increases
in debt concentrated among the riskiest rms.
In contrast, household borrowing remains
modest relative to income, and the debt
growth is concentrated among borrowers with
high credit scores. Key nancial institutions,
including the largest banks, continue to be well
capitalized and hold large quantities of liquid
assets. Funding risks in the nancial system
remain low relative to the period leading up to
the crisis.
International developments. After slowing in
2018, foreign economic growth appears to
have stabilized in the rst half of the year,
but at a restrained pace. While aggregate
activity in the advanced foreign economies
(AFEs) increased slowly from the soft patch
of late last year, activity in emerging Asia
generally struggled to gain a solid footing, and
several Latin American economies continued
to underperform. Growth abroad has been
held down in part by a slowdown in the
manufacturing sector against the backdrop
of softening global trade ows. With both
ination and activity in the AFEs remaining
subdued, AFE central banks took a more
accommodative policy stance.
Despite
trade tensions that weighed onnancial
markets, nancial conditions abroad generally
eased in the rst half of the year, supported
by accommodative communications by major
central banks. On balance, global equity prices
moved higher, sovereign yields in major foreign
economies declined, and sovereign bond
spreads in the emerging market economies
were little changed. Market-implied paths of
policy rates in AFEs generally declined.
Monetary Policy
Interest rate policy. In its meetings over the
rst half of 2019, the FOMC judged that the
stance of monetary policy was appropriate
to achieve the Committee’s objectives
of maximum employment and 2percent
ination, and it decided to maintain the target
range for the federal funds rate at 2¼ to
2½percent. These decisions reected incoming
information showing the solid fundamentals
of the U.S. economy supporting continued
growth and strong employment. For most of
this period, the Committee indicated that,
in light of global economic and nancial
developments and muted ination pressures, it
would be patient as it determines what future
adjustments to the target range for the federal
funds rate may be appropriate. At the June
FOMC meeting, however, the Committee
noted that uncertainties about the global and
domestic economic outlook had increased. In
light of these uncertainties and muted ination
pressures, the Committee indicated that it will
act as appropriate to sustain the expansion,
with a strong labor market and ination near
its symmetric 2percent objective.
In the most recent Summary of Economic
Projections, which was compiled at the time
of the June FOMC meeting, participants
generally revised down their individual
assessments of the appropriate path for
monetary policy relative to their assessments
at the time of the March meeting. (The
participants’ most recent economic
projections—released after the June FOMC
meeting—are discussed in more detail in Part3
of this report.) However, as the Committee
has continued to emphasize, the timing and
size of future adjustments to the target range
for the federal funds rate will depend on
the Committee’s assessment of realized and
expected economic conditions relative to its
objectives of maximum employment and
2percent ination.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 3
Balance sheet policy. Over the rst half of the
year, the FOMC made two announcements
regarding the longer-run policy implementa-
tion framework and its plans for normalizing
the balance sheet. Following its January
meeting, the Committee noted that it decided
to continue to implement monetary policy
in a regime with ample reserves. Consistent
with that decision, in March, the Committee
announced plans to conclude the reduction
of its aggregate securities holdings at the end
of September2019. (See the box “Framework
for Monetary Policy Implementation and
Normalization of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet” in Part 2.) The Committee is
prepared to adjust the details for completing
balance sheet normalization in light of
economic and nancial developments,
consistent with its policy objectives of
maximum employment and price stability.
Special Topics
Labor market conditions for lower- and
higher-educated workers. The labor market
has strengthened since the end of the last
recession, but the pattern of recovery has
varied across workers with dierent levels
of education. Workers with a college degree
or more experienced a swifter recovery in
employment, while those with a high school
degree or less had a much more delayed
recovery in employment. This pattern is
typical of business cycles, and recent research
sheds light on mechanisms that may lead to
dierences in the timing of recovery for lower-
and higher-educated workers. (See the box
“How Have Lower-Educated Workers Fared
since the Great Recession?” in Part 1.)
Global manufacturing and trade. Growth in
global trade and manufacturing has
weakened signicantly since 2017 even as
growth in services has held up. Trade policy
developments appear to have lowered trade
ows to some extent, while uncertainty
surrounding trade policy may be weighing
on investment. The global tech cycle and a
general slowdown in global demand, reecting
idiosyncratic factors specic to dierent
economies, have also likely weighed on
demand for traded goods. (See the box “The
Persistent Slowdown in Global Trade and
Manufacturing” in Part 1.)
Monetary policy rules. Monetary policy rules
are mathematical formulas that relate a policy
interest rate, such as the federal funds rate, to
a small number of other economic variables,
typically including the deviation of ination
from its target value and a measure of resource
slack in the economy. The prescriptions for
the policy interest rate from these rules can
provide helpful guidance for the FOMC.
This discussion presents ve policy rules—
illustrative of the many rules that have received
attention in the research literature—and
provides examples of two ways to compute
historical prescriptions of policy rules. (See
the box “Monetary Policy Rules and Their
Interactions with the Economy” in Part 2.)
Monetary policy implementation and balance
sheet normalization. Since the beginning of
this year, the FOMC has made important
decisions regarding its framework for
monetary policy implementation and the
process of normalizing the size of its balance
sheet. The Committee decided to continue to
implement monetary policy in a regime with
an ample supply of reserves and announced
that it intends to conclude the reduction
of its aggregate securities holdings in the
System Open Market Account at the end of
September2019. (See the box “Framework
for Monetary Policy Implementation and
Normalization of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet” in Part 2.)
5
Part 1
reCent eConomiC and finanCiaL deveLoPments
Total nonfarm (3-month)
50
100
150
200
250
300
Thousands of jobs
2019201720152013
1. Net change in payroll employment
Monthly
Total nonfarm (12-month)
N
OTE: The data are 3-month and 12-month moving averages.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Domestic Developments
The labor market strengthened further
during the rst half of 2019 but at a
slower pace than last year . . .
Labor market conditions have continued
to strengthen so far this year but at a pace
slower than last year. Total nonfarm payroll
employment has averaged gains of about
165,000 per month over the rst ve months
of 2019, according to the Bureau of Labor
Statistics. This pace is slower than the average
monthly gains in 2018, but it is faster than
what is needed to provide jobs for net new
entrants into the labor force as the working-
age population grows (gure1).
1
In April and May of this year, the
unemployment rate stood at 3.6percent,
¼percentage point lower than its level in
December2018 and its lowest level since 1969
(gure2). In addition, the unemployment rate
is ½percentage point below the median of
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
participants’ estimates of its longer-run
normal level.
2
In May, the labor force participation rate
(LFPR) for individuals 16 and over—that is,
the share of the population either working or
actively seeking work—was 62.8percent, and
it has changed little, on net, since late 2013.
The aging of the population is an important
contributor to an underlying downward trend
1.
Owing to population growth, roughly 115,000 to
145,000 jobs per month need to be created, on average, to
keep the unemployment rate constant with an unchanged
labor force participation rate. However, the participation
rate fell over the December to May period, reducing
the number of job gains that would have been needed.
There is considerable uncertainty around these estimates,
as the dierence between monthly payroll gains and
employment changes from the Current Population Survey
(the source of the unemployment and participation rates)
can be quite volatile over short periods.
2.
See the most recent economic projections that were
released after the June FOMC meeting in
Part 3
of this report.
6 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
in the overall participation rate. In particular,
members of the baby-boom cohort are
increasingly moving into their retirement years,
ages when labor force participation typically
falls. The at trajectory in the overall LFPR
is therefore consistent with strengthening
labor market conditions; indeed, the LFPR
for prime-age individuals (between 25 and
54years old), which is much less sensitive
to the eects of population aging, has been
rising over the past few years (gure3).
Combining both the unemployment rate and
the LFPR, the employment-to-population
ratio (EPOP) for individuals 16 and over—the
share of that segment of the population who
are working—was 60.6percent in May and
has been gradually increasing throughout the
expansion. The increase has been considerably
larger for those with at least some college
education than for those with no more than
a high school diploma. (The box “How Have
Lower-Educated Workers Fared since the
Employment-to-population ratio
Prime-age labor force
participation rate
56
58
60
62
64
66
68
Percent
80
81
82
83
84
85
20192016201320102007
3. Labor force participation rates and
employment-to-population ratio
Percent
Labor force participation rate
NOTE: The data are monthly. The prime-age labor force participation
rate is a percentage of the population aged 25 to 54. The labor force
participation rate and the employment-to-population ratio are
percentages of the population aged 16 and over.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
U-5
U-4
U-6
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent
2019201720152013201120092007
2. Measures of labor underutilization
Monthly
Unemployment rate
N
OTE: Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. U-4 measures total unemployed plus discouraged workers,
as a percentage of the labor force plus discouraged workers. Discouraged workers are a subset of marginally attached workers who are not currently
looking for work because they believe no jobs are available for them. U-5 measures total unemployed plus all marginally attached to the labor force, as a
percentage of the labor force plus persons marginally attached to the labor force. Marginally attached workers are not in the labor force, want and are
available for work, and have looked for a job in the past 12 months. U-6 measures total unemployed plus all marginally attached workers plus total
employed part time for economic reasons, as a percentage of the labor force plus all marginally attached workers. The shaded bar indicates a period of
business recession as dened by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 7
Great Recession?” discusses movements in the
EPOP by educational level over the current
expansion.)
Other indicators are also consistent with
strong labor market conditions. As reported in
the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
(JOLTS), the average of the private-sector job
openings rate over the rst four months of the
year was near its historical high, consistent
with surveys indicating that businesses see
vacancies as hard to ll. Similarly, the quits
rate in the JOLTS is also near the top of its
historical range, an indication that workers
are being bid away from their current jobs or
have become more condent that they can
successfully switch jobs if they wish to. This
interpretation accords well with surveys of
consumers that indicate households perceive
jobs as plentiful. The JOLTS layo rate and
the number of people ling initial claims for
unemployment insurance benets have both
remained quite low.
. . . and unemployment rates have fallen
for all major demographic groups over
the past several years
Dierences in unemployment rates across
ethnic and racial groups have narrowed in
recent years, as they typically do during
economic expansions, after having widened
during the recession (gure4). However,
unemployment rates for African Americans
and Hispanics remain substantially above
those for whites and Asians. The rise in LFPRs
for prime-age individuals over the past few
years has also been apparent in each of these
racial and ethnic groups (gure5).
Increases in labor compensation have
picked up but remain moderate by
historical standards . . .
Despite strong labor market conditions, the
available indicators generally suggest that
increases in hourly labor compensation have
remained moderate. The employment cost
index—a measure of both wages and the
cost to employers of providing benets—was
8 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
The relative underperformance of employment and
wage growth for lower-educated workers has been
a characteristic of all business cycles since at least
1980. This pattern is likely due, at least in part, to a
long-term downward trend in the demand for lower-
educated workers that is unrelated to the business cycle
and caused, perhaps, by changes in technology and
globalization.
3
To focus on the effects of business cycles
distinct from these longer-term trends, we examine
business cycles at the state level to estimate the
of Atlanta’s Wage Growth Tracker (WGT), which calculates
the median, year-over-year percent change in nominal
wages of individuals employed 12 months apart. The WGT
measure shows that median wage growth for workers with
a high school degree was lower than median wage growth
for workers with a college degree through 2015. Since then,
median wage growth for both groups has been similar.
3. The EPOP for lower-educated, prime-age individuals has
been trending lower for men since 1950 and for women since
2000, largely reecting the trends in those groups’ labor force
participation rates (LFPRs). For an overview of factors affecting
the LFPRs of prime-age individuals, see the box “The Labor
Force Participation Rate for Prime-Age Individuals” in Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2018), Monetary
Policy Report (Washington: Board of Governors, July),
pp.8–10, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
les/20180713_mprfullreport.pdf; and Congressional Budget
Ofce (2018), Factors Affecting the Labor Force Participation
of People Ages 25 to 54 (Washington: CBO, February, https://
www.cbo.gov/system/les/115th-congress-2017-2018/
reports/53452-lfpr.pdf).
The U.S. labor market has been strengthening since
the end of the Great Recession. Over this period, the
unemployment rate has fallen roughly 6percentage
points, and the employment-to-population ratio (EPOP)
for individuals between 25 and 54years old (prime
age) has increased about 4¼percentage points. How-
ever, labor market outcomes during the expansion have
been quite different for lower- and higher-educated
individuals. The EPOP for prime-age college graduates
declined about 2.5percentage points during the
recession, but it began a steady and sustained recovery
in 2010 and was nearly at its pre-recession level by
2018 (left panel of gure A). In contrast, the EPOP
for prime-age individuals with a high school degree
or less fell much more sharply during the recession
and lingered near its trough for several years before
it began to recover in 2014.
1
As of 2018, the EPOP
for lower-educated workers remained well below
its pre-recession level. In addition, real (or ination-
adjusted) hourly wages for lower-educated workers
fell more over the 2007–13 period than real wages for
college graduates (right panel of gure A). Real wages
subsequently picked up for both groups, but cumulative
real wage gains for lower-educated workers have only
recently caught up, in percentage terms, to those for
workers with college degrees.
2
1. The analysis excludes those with some college education
but not a four-year degree. The labor market experience of
such individuals, though, is similar to that of individuals with a
high school degree or less.
2. Another measure of wage growth using the same Current
Population Survey data source is the Federal Reserve Bank
How Have Lower-Educated Workers Fared since the Great Recession?
(continued)
A. Prime-age employment and wages by education, 2007–18
Real wages Employment-to-population ratios
Sta calculations using the Current Population Survey. SOURCE:
Percent change from 2007AnnualPercentage point change from 2007Annual
High school or less
6
5
4
3
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
201820162014201220102008
College plus
High school or less
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
+
_
0
201820162014201220102008
College plus
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 9
rate.
7
Indeed, real wages for lower-educated workers
rose faster over the past few years as the labor market
tightened, and total wage growth for those workers
since 2007 is now close to wage growth for more-
educated workers (as shown in the right panel of
gure A). Hotchkiss and Moore (2018) nd that
exposure to a low-unemployment economy is
particularly benecial for individuals who entered the
labor market during periods of high unemployment and
would otherwise face persistently worse labor market
outcomes.
8
Thus, periods of low unemployment may
particularly improve labor market outcomes of lower-
educated workers.
7. See Stephanie R. Aaronson, Mary C. Daly, William
Wascher, and David W. Wilcox (2019), “Okun Revisited: Who
Benets Most from a Strong Economy?” paper presented at
the Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Conference, held
at the Brookings Institution, Washington, March7–8, https://
www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2019/03/Okun-
Revisited-Who-Benets-Most-From-a-Strong-Economy.pdf.
8. See Julie L. Hotchkiss and Robert E. Moore (2018),
“Some Like It Hot: Assessing Longer-Term Labor Market
Benets from a High-Pressure Economy,” Andrew Young
School of Policy Studies Research Paper Series 18-01 (Atlanta:
Georgia State University, February), https://aysps.gsu.edu/
les/2018/03/18-01-HotchkissMoore-SomelikeitHot.pdf.
“typical” cyclical decline and recovery of employment
for both education groups.
The typical state-level business cycle shows a starkly
different evolution of employment for lower-educated
workers compared with that for workers with college
degrees. Typically in a recession, the EPOP declines
immediately for both groups, but the decline is deeper
and longer lasting for those with a high school degree
or less (gure B).
4
Once that group’s EPOP begins a
sustained recovery, though, it increases at a more rapid
pace than the EPOP for those with a college degree.
These results indicate that the EPOP for lower-educated
workers may not fully recover for at least eight years,
on average, following the end of a recession.
The differences in labor market outcomes over
the business cycle for different education groups may
in part be due to employers changing their hiring
standards. Some research shows that employers raise
skill requirements for new hires in a recession and then
gradually lower skill requirements as the labor market
recovers.
5
Other research suggests that when high-
skilled workers lose their jobs during recessions, they
take jobs that require fewer skills, making these jobs
less likely to be lled by low-skilled individuals.
6
This
pattern could at least in part explain the differences in
labor market outcomes for lower- and higher-educated
workers since the most recent recession.
As the unemployment rate falls and employers relax
their hiring standards, more opportunities are likely to
open for lower-educated workers. Aaronson and others
(2019) present some evidence that disadvantaged
groups, such as nonwhite individuals and those with
less education, benet more from further improvement
in the labor market relative to more advantaged groups
when the unemployment rate is below its natural
4. For ease of interpretation, we dene a typical recession
as a state experiencing a temporary 1percent decline in state
output growth in a given year, returning to normal growth
in the following year. To get the estimated effect of a larger
or smaller recession, simply multiply the estimates by the
specied decline in output growth.
5. See Brad Hershbein and Lisa B. Kahn (2018), “Do
Recessions Accelerate Routine-Biased Technological Change?
Evidence from Vacancy Postings,American Economic Review,
vol. 108 (July), pp. 1737–72; and Alicia Sasser Modestino,
Daniel Shoag, and Joshua Ballance (2016), “Downskilling:
Changes in Employer Skill Requirements over the Business
Cycle,Labour Economics, vol. 41 (August), pp. 333–47.
6. See Regis Barnichon and Yanos Zylberberg (2019),
“Underemployment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment,
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 11 (April),
pp. 40–78.
High school or less 1.0
.5
+
_
0
.5
Percentage points
B. Response of EPOP by education to state-level
recessions
College plus
0246810
Year relative to shock
N: EPOP refers to the employment-to-population ratio. Shaded
areas are 95 percent condence bands. Data extend from 1978 through
2018.
S: Tomaz Cajner, John Coglianese, and Joshua Montes (2019),
“Cyclical Dynamics of the U.S. Labor Market,unpublished paper,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of
Research and Statistics, March.
10 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
2¾percent higher in March of 2019 relative to
its year-earlier level (gure6). Compensation
per hour in the business sector—a broad-
based but volatile measure of wages, salaries,
and benets—rose 1½percent over the four
quarters ending in 2019:Q1, less than the
annual increases over the preceding couple of
years. Among measures that do not account
for benets, average hourly earnings rose
3.1percent in May relative to 12 months
earlier, a slightly faster rate of increase
than during the same period of a year ago.
According to the Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta, the median 12-month wage growth
of individuals reporting to the Current
Population Survey increased about 3¾percent
in May, near the upper portion of its range
over the past couple of years.
3
3. The Atlanta Fed’s measure diers from others in
that it measures the wage growth only of workers who
were employed both in the current survey month and
12months earlier.
Black or African American
Asian
Hispanic or Latino
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent
2019201720152013201120092007
4. Unemployment rate by race and ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE
:Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. Persons whose ethnicity is identied as Hispanic or Latino
may be of any race. The shaded bar indicates a period of business recession as dened by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Black or African American
Asian
Hispanic or Latino
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
Percent
2019201720152013201120092007
5. Prime-age labor force participation rate by race and
ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE: The prime-age labor force participation rate is a percentage of
the population aged 25 to 54. Persons whose ethnicity is identied as
Hispanic or Latino may be of any race. The data are seasonally adjusted
by Board sta and are 3-month moving averages. The shaded bar
indicates a period of business recession as dened by the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 11
. . . and likely have been restrained by
slow growth in labor productivity over
much of the expansion
These moderate rates of hourly compensation
gains likely reect the osetting inuences of
a strengthening labor market and productivity
growth that has been weak through much
of the expansion. From 2008 to 2017, labor
productivity increased a little more than
1percent per year, on average, well below
the average pace from 1996 to 2007 of nearly
3percent and also below the average gain
in the 1974–95 period (gure7). Although
considerable debate remains about the reasons
for the slowdown in productivity growth
over this period, the weakness may be partly
attributable to the sharp pullback in capital
investment during the most recent recession
and the relatively slow recovery that followed.
More recently, however, labor productivity
rose 1¾percent in 2018 and picked up
further in the rst quarter of 2019.
4
While it
is uncertain whether this faster rate of growth
will persist, a sustained pickup in productivity
growth, as well as additional labor market
strengthening, would support stronger gains in
labor compensation.
Price ination has dipped below
2percent this year
Consumer price ination has moved down
below the FOMC’s objective of 2percent this
year.
5
As measured by the 12-month change
in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures (PCE), ination is estimated to
have been 1.5percent in May after being at or
4. In the rst quarter, labor productivity surged
3½percent at an annual rate, bringing the four-quarter
change to 2½percent, reecting a strong pickup in
business-sector output and unusual weakness in hours
relative to measured gains in payroll employment. This
weakness is attributable to a steep decline in a volatile
component of hours that is not directly measured in the
Bureau of Labor Statistics’ establishment survey.
5. The increases in taris on imported goods last year
likely provided only a small boost to ination in 2018 and
in the rst half of this year.
1
2
3
4
Percent, annual rate
7. Change in business-sector output per hour
1948–
73
1974–
95
1996–
2000
2001–
07
2008–
17
2018 2019
N
OTE
: Changes are measured from Q4 of the year immediately
preceding the period through Q4 of the nal year of the period except
2019 changes, which are calculated from 2018:Q1 to 2019:Q1.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Employment
cost index,
private sector
Atlanta Fed’s
Wage Growth Tracker
Average hourly earnings,
private sector
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent change from year earlier
201920172015201320112009200720052003
6. Measures of change in hourly compensation
Compensation per hour,
business sector
N
OTE: Business-sector compensation is on a 4-quarter percent change
basis. For the private-sector employment cost index, change is over the
12 months ending in the last month of each quarter; for private-sector
average hourly earnings, the data are 12-month percent changes and
begin in March 2007; for the Atlanta Fed’s Wage Growth Tracker, the
data are shown as a 3-month moving average of the 12-month percent
change.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
Wage Growth Tracker; all via Haver Analytics.
12 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
above 2percent for much of 2018 (gure8).
Core PCE ination—which excludes consumer
food and energy prices that are often quite
volatile, and which therefore typically provides
a better indication than the total measure of
where overall ination will be in the future—
also moved lower in recent months and is
estimated to have been 1.6percent over the
12 months ending in May. The slowing in
core ination to date reects particularly low
readings in the rst three months of the year
that appear due to idiosyncratic price declines
in a number of specic categories such as
apparel, used cars, and banking services and
portfolio management services. Indeed, in
April and May, core ination accelerated,
posting larger average monthly gains than in
the rst quarter.
The trimmed mean PCE price index,
produced by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas, provides an alternative way to purge
ination of transitory inuences, and it is less
sensitive than the core index to idiosyncratic
price movements such as those noted earlier.
6
The 12-month change in this measure was
2percent in May.
Oil prices rebounded through the spring
but have moved down recently . . .
After dropping sharply late last year, the
Brent price of crude oil moved up to almost
$75per barrel in mid-April, partly reecting
declines in production in Iran and Venezuela
and voluntary supply cuts by other OPEC
members and partner countries (gure9).
More recently, however, prices have fallen back
to around $65 per barrel because of concerns
about global growth. The changes in oil prices
have contributed to similar movements in
retail gasoline prices, which rose through early
spring but have also fallen back recently.
6. The trimmed mean index excludes whichever prices
showed the largest increases or decreases in a given
month. Note that, since 1995, changes in the trimmed
mean index have averaged about 0.3percentage point
above core PCE ination and 0.2percentage point above
total PCE ination.
Brent spot price
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
Dollars per barrel
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
9. Spot and futures prices for crude oil
Weekly
24-month-ahead
futures contracts
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data. The weekly data
begin on Thursdays and extend through July 1, 2019.
S
OURCE: ICE Brent Futures via Bloomberg.
Excluding food
and energy
Trimmed mean
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
12-month percent change
20192018201720162015201420132012
8. Change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures
Monthly
Total
SOURCE: For trimmed mean, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; for all
else, Bureau of Economic Analysis; all via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 13
. . . and prices of imports other than
energy fell
Nonfuel import prices, before accounting
for the eects of taris on the price of
imported goods, have continued to decline
from their mid-2018 peak, responding to
dollar appreciation, lower foreign ination,
and declines in non-oil commodity prices
(gure10).
7
In particular, prices of industrial
metals have fallen in recent months, partly on
concerns about weak global demand.
Survey-based measures of ination
expectations have been stable . . .
Expectations of ination likely inuence actual
ination by aecting wage- and price-setting
decisions. Survey-based measures of ination
expectations at medium- and longer-term
horizons have remained generally stable over
the past year. In the Survey of Professional
Forecasters, conducted by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the median
expectation for the annual rate of increase in
the PCE price index over the next 10years
has been very close to 2percent for the past
several years (gure11). In the University
of Michigan Surveys of Consumers, the
median value for ination expectations over
the next 5 to 10years has uctuated around
2½percent since the end of 2016, though this
level is about ¼percentage point lower than
had prevailed through 2014. In the Survey
of Consumer Expectations, conducted by
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the
median of respondents’ expected ination
rate three years hence has uctuated between
2½percent and 3percent over the past
veyears.
. . . while market-based measures of
ination compensation have come down
since the rst half of 2018
Ination expectations can also be gauged
by market-based measures of ination
7. Published import price indexes exclude taris.
However, taris add to the prices that purchasers of
imports actually pay.
Nonfuel import prices
94
96
98
100
102
January 2014 = 100
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
201920182017201620152014
10. Nonfuel import prices and industrial metals indexes
January 2014 = 100
Industrial metals
N
OTE: The data for nonfuel import prices are monthly. The data for
industrial metals are a monthly average of daily data and extend through
June 28, 2019.
S
OURCE: For nonfuel import prices, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for
industrial metals, S&P GSCI Industrial Metals Spot Index via Haver
Analytics.
Michigan survey expectations
for next 5 to 10 years
1
2
3
4
Percent
20192017201520132011200920072005
SPF expectations
for next 10 years
11. Median ination expectations
NOTE: The Michigan survey data are monthly and extend through
June 2019. The SPF data for ination expectations for personal
consumption expenditures are quarterly and extend from 2007:Q1
through 2019:Q2.
SOURCE: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF).
14 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
compensation. However, the inference
is not straightforward, because market-
based measures can be importantly aected
by changes in premiums that provide
compensation for bearing ination and
liquidity risks. Measures of longer-term
ination compensation—derived either from
dierences between yields on nominal Treasury
securities and those on comparable-maturity
Treasury Ination-Protected Securities
(TIPS) or from ination swaps—tend to fall
when markets are volatile because of the
incorporation of liquidity risks. Such declines
occurred around the turn of the year and
again in May and June, when market volatility
picked up again. Despite the uctuations this
year, these measures of ination compensation
remain notably below levels that prevailed in
the summer of 2018 (gure12).
8
The TIPS-
based measure of 5-to-10-year-forward
ination compensation and the analogous
measure from ination swaps are now about
1¾percent and 2percent, respectively, with
both measures below their respective ranges
that prevailed for most of the 10years before
the start of the notable declines in mid-2014.
9
Real gross domestic product growth was
strong in the rst quarter, but there are
recent signs of slowing
Real gross domestic product (GDP) rose at an
annual rate of 3percent in 2018 (gure13).
In the rst quarter, real GDP again moved
up at an annual rate of around 3percent.
8. Ination compensation implied by the TIPS
breakeven ination rate is based on the dierence, at
comparable maturities, between yields on nominal
Treasury securities and yields on TIPS, which are indexed
to the total consumer price index (CPI). Ination swaps
are contracts in which one party makes payments of
certain xed nominal amounts in exchange for cash ows
that are indexed to cumulative CPI ination over some
horizon. Ination compensation derived from ination
swaps typically exceeds TIPS-based compensation, but
week-to-week movements in the two measures are highly
correlated.
9. As these measures are based on the CPI ination
index, one should probably subtract about ¼percentage
point—the average dierential with PCE ination
and CPI ination over the past two decades—to infer
ination compensation on a PCE price basis.
1
2
3
4
5
Percent, annual rate
20192018201720162015201420132012
13. Change in real gross domestic product and gross
domestic income
Q1
S
OURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Gross domestic product
Gross domestic income
Private domestic nal purchases
Ination swaps
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Percent
20192017201520132011
12. 5-to-10-year-forward ination compensation
Weekly
TIPS breakeven rates
N
OTE
:The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend through
June 28, 2019. TIPS is Treasury Ination-Protected Securities.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Barclays; Federal Reserve
Board sta estimates.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 15
However, there are indications that growth will
moderate in the second quarter.
10
Net exports
and business inventories provided a sizable
boost to rst-quarter GDP growth, but their
contributions appear to have reversed in the
months following. Notably, private domestic
nal purchases—that is, nal purchases by
households and businesses, which tend to
provide a better indication of future GDP
growth than most other components of overall
spending—posted only a modest increase in
the rst quarter. The slowing that occurred
in consumer spending appears to have been
temporary, but the slowing in business xed
investment appears to be more persistent.
Manufacturing output fell in the rst quarter,
and it moved down further in April before
posting a small gain in May. Although lower
production levels of motor vehicles and
aircraft were important contributors to the
weakness, the recent declines in manufacturing
were broad based.
11
Nevertheless, the economic
expansion continues to be abetted by steady
job gains, increases in household wealth,
expansionary scal policy, and still-supportive
domestic nancial conditions, including
moderate borrowing costs and easy access to
credit for many households and businesses.
Growth in business xed investment has
softened after strong gains in 2018
Investment spending by businesses rose
rapidly in 2018 but appears to have decelerated
sharply this year. In the rst quarter, growth
slowed to an annual rate of 4½percent, while
new orders for nondefense capital goods,
excluding the volatile aircraft category, have
declined modestly, on balance, in recent
months (gure14). In addition, forward-
10. It is worth noting that gross domestic income
(GDI) has been notably weaker than GDP. GDI is
reported to have risen only 1.7percent in the rst quarter
relative to the same period of a year ago, 1½percentage
points less than measured GDP growth. GDP and GDI
measure the same economic concept, and any dierence
between the two gures reects measurement error.
11. Recently, a large aircraft manufacturer slowed
its production and temporarily halted deliveries of
an aircraft model. This production slowdown lowers
manufacturing output and generates a small drag on real
GDP growth in the rst half of the year.
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
Percent, annual rate
20192018201720162015201420132012
14. Change in real private nonresidential xed
investment
Q1
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Structures
Equipment and intangible capital
16 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
looking indicators of business spending such
as capital spending plans have deteriorated
amid downbeat business sentiment and prot
expectations from industry analysts, reportedly
reecting trade tensions and concerns about
global growth.
By contrast, activity in the housing sector
had been declining but recently shows
signs of stabilizing
Residential investment fell in 2018 and
declined further in the rst quarter. More
recently, the pace of construction activity
appears to have stabilized as housing starts for
single-family and multifamily housing units
rose, on average, in April and May (gure15).
Existing home sales moved higher as well
over the same period, while new home sales
moved down a bit following a sizable increase
in the rst quarter (gure16). Consumers’
perceptions of homebuying conditions and
housing aordability have improved, which is
consistent with the declines in mortgage rates
this year and the slowing in growth of home
prices (gure17).
Ongoing improvements in the labor
market and gains in wealth continue to
support household income and consumer
spending . . .
After increasing at a moderate pace of
2½percent in 2018 as a whole, real consumer
spending slowed considerably in the rst
quarter (gure18). However, incoming data
suggest that consumer spending picked up
in recent months, with PCE in May up at
an annual rate of 2½percent relative to the
average level in the fourth quarter.
Real disposable personal income (DPI), a
measure of households’ after-tax purchasing
power, increased at a solid annual rate of
3percent in 2018; however, so far this year,
growth in real DPI has been more moderate
despite strong gains in wage and salary income.
With consumer spending rising more than
disposable income so far this year, the personal
saving rate moved down from an average of
Multifamily starts
Single-family
permits
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
Millions of units, annual rate
2019201720152013201120092007
15. Private housing starts and permits
Monthly
Single-family starts
S
OURCE: U.S. Census Bureau via Haver Analytics.
Existing home sales
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
Millions, annual rate
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
2019201720152013201120092007
16. New and existing home sales
Millions, annual rate
New home sales
N
OTE: Data are monthly. New home sales includes only single-family
sales. Existing home sales includes single-family, condo, townhome, and
co-op sales.
S
OURCE: For new home sales, U.S. Census Bureau; for existing home
sales, National Association of Realtors; all via Haver Analytics.
Mortgage rates
115
130
145
160
175
190
205
Index
3
4
5
6
7
20192017201520132011
17. Mortgage rates and housing aordability
Percent
Housing aordability index
N
OTE: The housing aordability index data are monthly through
April 2019, and the mortgage rate data are weekly through June 27, 2019.
At an index value of 100, a median-income family has exactly enough
income to qualify for a median-priced home mortgage. Housing
aordability is seasonally adjusted by Board sta.
S
OURCE: For housing aordability index, National Association of
Realtors via Haver Analytics; for mortgage rates, Freddie Mac Primary
Mortgage Market Survey.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 17
6½percent in the fourth quarter to around
6percent in May (gure19).
Ongoing gains in household wealth have likely
continued to support consumer spending.
House prices, which are of particular
importance for the balance sheet positions
of a large portion of households, continued
to increase through May, although at a more
moderate pace than in recent years (gure20).
In addition, U.S. equity prices, which fell
sharply at the end of 2018, have rebounded
this year. Buoyed by increases in home and
equity prices, aggregate household net worth
moved up to 6.8 times household income in
the rst quarter (gure21).
. . . and consumer sentiment remains
strong
Consumers have remained upbeat. Although
the Michigan index of consumer sentiment
dipped at the turn of the year, it has since
rallied, and the sentiment measure from the
Conference Board survey also climbed in the
second quarter from its rst-quarter level
(gure22). In June, both the Michigan and
the Conference Board indexes of consumer
sentiment were about in the middle of their
ranges over the past few years.
Borrowing conditions for households
remain generally favorable . . .
Despite increases in interest rates for consumer
loans and some reported further tightening
in credit card lending standards, nancing
conditions for consumers largely remain
supportive of growth in household spending.
Consumer credit expanded at a moderate
pace in the rst quarter, rising faster than
disposable income (gure23). Mortgage
credit has continued to be readily available
for households with solid credit proles but
remains noticeably tighter than before the
most recent recession for borrowers with
low credit scores. Standards for automotive
loans have been generally stable, and
overall delinquency rates for these loans
were little changed in the rst quarter at a
3
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent, annual rate
2019201820172016201520142013
18. Change in real personal consumption expenditures
and disposable personal income
H1
NOTE: The values for 2019:H1 are the annualized May/Q4 changes.
S
OURCE: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis via
Haver Analytics.
Personal consumption expenditures
Disposable personal income
CoreLogic
price index
S&P/Case-Shiller
national index
20
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
Percent change from year earlier
201920172015201320112009
20. Prices of existing single-family houses
Monthly
Zillow index
N
OTE: The data for the S&P/Case-Shiller index extend through April
2019.
S
OURCE: CoreLogic Home Price Index; Zillow; S&P/Case-Shiller U.S.
National Home Price Index. The S&P/Case-Shiller Index is a product of
S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its aliates. (For Dow Jones
Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
2
4
6
8
10
12
PercentMonthly
2019201720152013201120092007
19. Personal saving rate
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
18 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
moderate level.
Financing
conditions in the
student loan market remain rm, with over
90percent of such credit being extended by
the federal government. After peaking in 2013,
delinquencies on such loans have been gradually
declining, reecting in part the continued
improvements in the labor market.
. . . while corporate nancing conditions
tightened somewhat relative to last year
but remained accommodative overall
Aggregate ows of credit to large nonnancial
rms remained strong in the rst quarter,
supported in part by relatively low interest
rates and accommodative nancing conditions
(gure24). The gross issuance of corporate
bonds, which had fallen substantially in
December, rebounded in the rst quarter as
market volatility receded. After increasing
notably in late 2018, spreads on both
investment- and speculative-grade corporate
bonds over comparable-maturity Treasury
securities have both declined, on net, this
year as investors’ risk appetite seems to
have recovered. In April, respondents to the
Senior Loan Ocer Opinion Survey on Bank
Lending Practices, or SLOOS, reported that
demand for commercial and industrial loans
weakened in the rst quarter even as lending
standards remained unchanged and terms for
such loans eased.
12
However, banks reported
tightening lending standards on all categories
of commercial real estate loans. Meanwhile,
nancing conditions for small businesses have
remained generally accommodative, but credit
growth has been subdued.
Net exports supported GDP growth in
the rst quarter
After being a small drag on U.S. real GDP
growth last year, net exports, which can have
sizable swings from quarter to quarter, added
about 1percentage point to the rate of growth
in the rst quarter. Real U.S. exports increased
at an annual rate of about 5½percent, as
12. The SLOOS is available on the Board’s website at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/data/sloos/sloos.htm.
Michigan survey
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
Index
10
30
50
70
90
110
130
150
170
2019201620132010200720042001
Index
22. Indexes of consumer sentiment
Conference Board
N
OTE: The data are monthly and extend through June 2019. The
Conference Board data are indexed to 100 in 1985; the Michigan survey
data are indexed to 100 in 1966.
S
OURCE: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Conference
Board.
Consumer credit
Mortgages
Sum
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
Percent change from year earlier
2019201720152013201120092007
23. Changes in household debt
Quarterly
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financial
Accounts of the United States.”
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
Ratio
2019201620132010200720042001
21. Wealth-to-income ratio
Quarterly
NOTE: The series is the ratio of household net worth to disposable
personal income.
S
OURCE: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release
Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the United States”; for income, Bureau of
Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 19
exports of agricultural products and auto-
mobiles expanded robustly. Real imports fell
2percent following solid increases in 2018
(gure25). Nominal goods trade data through
May suggest that exports edged down in the
second quarter, while imports were about at.
The available data suggest that the trade decit
and the current account in the rst half of the
year were little changed as a percent of GDP
from 2018 (gure26).
Federal scal policy actions boosted
economic growth in 2018 but had a
smaller effect on rst-quarter real GDP
because of the partial government
shutdown . . .
Fiscal policy at the federal level boosted GDP
growth in 2018 because of lower personal and
business income taxes from the Tax Cuts and
Jobs Act of 2017 and because of an increase in
federal purchases due to the Bipartisan Budget
Act of 2018.
13
After increasing 2¾percent in
2018, federal government purchases were at in
the rst quarter of 2019, reecting the eects
of the partial federal government shutdown
(gure27). The government shutdown, which
was in eect from December22 through
January25, held down GDP growth in the rst
quarter, largely because of the lost work of
furloughed federal government workers and
aected federal contractors. That said, federal
purchases are expected to rebound in the
second quarter.
The federal unied budget decit widened in
scal year 2018 to around 4percent of nominal
GDP from 3½percent of GDP in 2017
because receipts moved lower, to 16percent of
GDP (gure28). Expenditures are currently
around 21percent of GDP, slightly above
the level that prevailed in the decade before
the start of the 2007–09 recession. The ratio
13. The Joint Committee on Taxation estimated
that the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act would reduce average
annual tax revenue by a little more than 1percent of
GDP starting in 2018 and for several years thereafter.
This revenue estimate does not account for the potential
macroeconomic eects of the legislation.
40
20
+
_
0
20
40
60
80
Billions of dollars, monthly rate
2019201720152013201120092007
24. Selected components of net debt nancing for
nonnancial businesses
Sum
Q1
Commercial paper
Bonds
Bank loans
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financial
Accounts of the United States.”
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent, annual rate
20192018201720162015
25. Change in real imports and exports of goods
and services
Q1
S
OURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Imports
Exports
Current account
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
+
_
0
Percent of nominal GDP
2019201720152013201120092007200520032001
26. U.S. trade and current account balances
Annual
Trade
N
OTE: GDP is gross domestic product. The dots refer to the current
account and trade balances in the rst quarter of 2019.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
20 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Percent of nominal GDPQuarterly
29. Federal government debt held by the public
1969 1979 1989 1999 2009 2019
N
OTE: The data for gross domestic product (GDP) are at an annual
rate. Federal debt held by the public equals federal debt less Treasury
securities held in federal employee dened benet retirement accounts,
evaluated at the end of the quarter.
S
OURCE: For GDP, Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver
Analytics; for federal debt, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release
Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the United States.”
of federal debt held by the public to nominal
GDP rose to around 77percent in scal 2018
and was quite elevated relative to historical
norms (gure29). The Congressional Budget
Oce projects that this ratio will rise further
over the next several years.
. . . and the scal position of most state
and local governments is stable
The scal position of most state and local
governments is stable, although there is a
range of experiences across these governments.
The revenue of state governments has grown
moderately in recent quarters, as the economic
expansion continues to push up income and
sales tax collections. At the local level, property
tax collections continue to rise, pushed higher
by past house price gains. Real state and local
government purchases grew modestly last
year; however, outlays have surged so far this
year, driven largely by a boost in construction
spending. State and local infrastructure
spending was weak for many years, and there
appears to be demand for higher expenditures
in this area. State and local government
payrolls expanded slowly last year and over
the rst ve months of 2019, and employment
by these governments remains below its peak
before the current expansion.
Financial Developments
The expected path of the federal funds
rate over the next several years has
moved down
Market-based measures of the expected
path for the federal funds rate over the next
several years have declined substantially since
the end of 2018 (gure30). Various factors
contributed to this shift, including increased
investor concerns about downside risks to
the global economic outlook and rising trade
tensions. In addition, investors reportedly
interpreted FOMC communications over
the rst half of 2019 as signaling the Federal
Reserve is likely to lower the target range
for the federal funds rate in light of muted
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
Percent, annual rate
20192018201720162015201420132012
27. Change in real government expenditures on
consumption and investment
Q1
N
OTE: The federal value for 2019:Q1 is -0.05.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Federal
State and local
Expenditures
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
Percent of nominal GDP
20192016201320102007200420011998
Annual
28. Federal receipts and expenditures
Receipts
N
OTE: Through 2018, receipts and expenditures are for scal years
(October to September); gross domestic product (GDP) is for the four
quarters ending in Q3. For 2019, receipts and expenditures are for the
12 months ending in May; GDP is the average of 2018:Q4 and 2019:Q1.
Receipts and expenditures are on a unied-budget basis.
S
OURCE: Oce of Management and Budget via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 21
ination pressures and uncertainties about the
global economic outlook.
Survey-based measures of the expected path
of the policy rate also shifted down relative
to the levels observed at the end of 2018.
According to the results of the most recent
Survey of Primary Dealers and Survey of
Market Participants, both conducted by
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York just
before the June FOMC meeting, the median
of respondents’ modal projections implies a
declining trajectory for the target range of
the federal funds rate for 2019, which attens
out in 2020. Relative to the December survey,
the median of these projections moved down
50 basis points for July2019 and 100 basis
points for December2019.
14
Additionally,
market-based measures of uncertainty about
the policy rate approximately one to two years
ahead increased, on balance, from their levels
at the end of last December.
The nominal Treasury yield curve has
moved down and continued to atten
Since the end of 2018, the nominal Treasury
yield curve shifted down and attened
further, with the 2-, 5-, and 10-year nominal
Treasury yields all declining about 70 basis
points on net (gure31). The decrease in
Treasury yields, which is consistent with the
revision in market participants’ expectations
for the path of policy rates, largely reects
FOMC communications as well as investors’
concerns about the global economic outlook
and the escalation of trade disputes. Option-
implied volatility on swap rates—an indicator
of uncertainty about Treasury yields—has
increased notably, on net, since the beginning
of the year. In particular, measures of near-
14. The results of the Survey of Primary Dealers and
the Survey of Market Participants are available on the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s website at https://
www.newyorkfed.org/markets/primarydealer_survey_
questions.html and https://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/survey_market_participants, respectively.
2-year
5-year
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent
20192017201520132011200920072005
31. Yields on nominal Treasury securities
Daily
10-year
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury via Haver Analytics.
July 1, 2019
1.25
1.50
1.75
2.00
2.25
2.50
Percent
20232022202120202019
30. Market-implied federal funds rate path
Quarterly
Dec. 28, 2018
N
OTE: The federal funds rate path is implied by quotes on overnight
index swaps—a derivative contract tied to the eective federal funds rate.
The implied path as of July 1, 2019, is compared with that as o
f
December 28, 2018. The path is estimated with a spline approach,
assuming a term premium of 0 basis points. The July 1, 2019, path
extends through March 2023 and the December 28, 2018, path through
December 2022.
S
OURCE: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
22 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
High-yield
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Percentage points
20192017201520132011200920072005
33. Corporate bond yields, by securities rating
Daily
Investment-grade
N
OTE: Investment-grade is the 10-year triple-B, which reects the
eective yield of the ICE BofAML 7-to-10-year triple-B U.S. Corporate
Index (C4A4). High-yield is the 10-year high-yield and reects the
eective yield of the ICE BofAML 7-to-10-year U.S. Cash Pay High
Yield Index (J4A0). Data extend through June 26, 2019.
S
OURCE: ICE Bank of America Merrill Lynch Indices, used with
permission.
term interest rate uncertainty have reached the
levels seen at the end of 2018.
Yields on 30-year agency mortgage-backed
securities (MBS)—an important factor
inuencing mortgage interest rates—decreased
in line with the decline in the 10-year nominal
Treasury yield and remained low by historical
standards (gure32). Likewise, yields on both
investment-grade and high-yield corporate
debt declined signicantly from the levels
in late 2018 and stayed very low (gure33).
Despite widening in May, the spreads on
corporate bond yields over comparable-
maturity Treasury yields have narrowed, on
net, over the rst half of 2019 and are close to
their historical medians.
Broad equity price indexes increased on net
After declining sharply at the end of 2018,
broad U.S. stock market indexes have
recovered, on net, over the rst half of 2019
(gure34). The broad rebound in stock
prices—which included all major economic
sectors—was reportedly supported by Federal
Reserve communications that were perceived
as more accommodative than previously
anticipated. Stocks uctuated in May and
June as downside risks and trade tensions
were oset by further expectations of easier
monetary policy.
Measures of implied and realized stock price
volatility for the S&P 500 index declined
notably on net. Following the highs seen at the
end of 2018, these volatility measures declined
until late April, with the VIX—a measure
of implied volatility—returning to near the
10th percentile of its historical distribution
and with realized volatility close to the 30th
percentile of its historical range (gure35). At
the beginning of May, following the escalation
of trade tensions, these volatility measures
increased and have remained elevated since
then, but they have stayed well below the high
levels of December and now stand close to
their historical medians. Several measures of
nancial conditions that aggregate large sets
Yield
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
Basis points
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
20192017201520132011200920072005
32. Yield and spread on agency mortgage-backed
securities
Percent
Spread
N
OTE: The data are daily. Yield shown is for the Fannie Mae 30-year
current coupon, the coupon rate at which new mortgage-backed
securities would be priced at par, or face, value. Spread shown is to the
average of the 5- and 10-year nominal Treasury yields. Data extend
through June 26, 2019.
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury; Barclays Live.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 23
of nancial data into summary indexes eased
considerably since the end of 2018 but have
tightened a bit since the beginning of May, in
line with the decline in stock prices over that
month, and have remained relatively elevated
since then. (For a discussion of nancial
stability issues, see the box “Developments
Related to Financial Stability.”)
Markets for Treasury securities, mortgage-
backed securities, and municipal bonds
have functioned well
Available indicators of Treasury market
functioning have generally remained stable
since the beginning of 2019, with a variety of
measures—including bid-ask spreads, bid sizes,
and estimates of transaction costs—displaying
few signs of liquidity pressures. Liquidity
conditions in the agency MBS market were
also generally stable. Credit conditions in
municipal bond markets remained stable as
well, with yield spreads on 20-year general
obligation municipal bonds over comparable-
maturity Treasury securities declining
somewhat on net.
Money market rates were little changed
Rates across money markets were little
changed, on balance, in the rst half of 2019.
Conditions in domestic short-term funding
markets continued to be broadly stable since
the end of 2018. Overnight secured and
unsecured rates declined in line with the
technical adjustment announced after the May
FOMC meeting, which lowered the interests
paid on required and excess reserve balances
by 5 basis points. Other short-term interest
rates, including those on commercial paper
and negotiable certicates of deposit, were also
little changed since the beginning of the year.
Bank credit continued to expand, and
bank protability remained robust
Credit provided by commercial banks to
fund businesses as well as commercial and
residential real estate continued to grow in
2019, albeit at a slower pace than in the second
S&P 500 index
25
50
75
100
125
150
175
200
December 31, 1999 = 100
20192017201520132011200920072005
34. Equity prices
Daily
Dow Jones bank index
S
OURCE: Standard & Poor’s Dow Jones Indices via Bloomberg. (For
Dow Jones Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents
page.)
VIX
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Percent
20192017201520132011200920072005
35. S&P 500 volatility
Daily
Realized volatility
N
OTE: The VIX is a measure of implied volatility that represents the
expected annualized change in the S&P 500 index over the following 30
days. For realized volatility, ve-minute S&P 500 returns are used in an
exponentially weighted moving average with 75 percent of weight
distributed over the past 20 days.
S
OURCE: Cboe Volatility Index® (VIX®) accessed via Bloomberg;
Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
24 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
(gure B). Rapid debt growth, while broad based across
different parts of the business sector, is concentrated
among the riskiest rms, and there are signs that credit
standards for new leveraged loans are weak and have
deteriorated further over the past six months. In the
corporate bond market, the distribution of credit ratings
among investment-grade bonds has worsened, with
the share of bonds rated Baa (or triple-B) reaching
near-record levels. While broader corporate credit
performance remains solid amid a growing economy
and debt-service costs are relatively low, a broader
repricing of risk or a slowdown in economic activity
could pose notable risks to borrowing rms and their
creditors. Such developments could increase the
downside risk to economic activity more generally.
In contrast, in the household sector, debt growth is
concentrated among borrowers with high credit scores,
and the debt-to-GDP ratio continues to trend down
(gure B).
Vulnerabilities stemming from leverage at nancial
institutions remain low. Capital relative to risk-weighted
The framework used by the Federal Reserve Board
for assessing the resilience of the U.S. nancial system
focuses on nancial vulnerabilities in four broad
areas: asset valuations, household and business debt,
leverage in the nancial sector, and funding risks.
The Financial Stability Report published on May6,
2019, presents the most recent, detailed assessment
of these vulnerabilities.
1
This discussion summarizes
its key ndings, updated, where appropriate, to reect
developments since its publication.
Asset valuations remain somewhat elevated in a
number of markets. Treasury term premiums are near
record lows. Forward-looking measures of Treasury
market volatility have recently increased, especially
for shorter-dated Treasury securities. Equity prices
appear to be somewhat elevated relative to earnings,
with the forward equity price-to-earnings ratio for
the S&P500 remaining above the median value of its
historical distribution since the mid-1980s (gureA).
In commercial real estate markets, capitalization
rates remain at historically low levels. Residential real
estate prices are also somewhat high relative to rents
(accounting for borrowing costs and long-run trends),
although house price growth slowed materially in the
past year. Valuation pressures in the leveraged loan
market eased somewhat in recent months, and the
spreads on lower-rated leveraged loans are now above
the median value over the past 20years. In corporate
bond markets, spreads of 10-year corporate bonds
over benchmark rates are close to the median of their
historical distributions.
Vulnerabilities associated with total private-sector
credit remain at a moderate level relative to the past
several decades, and total debt has advanced roughly
in line with economic activity over the past ve years.
Leverage in the business sector remains near its highest
level in the past 20years, and business debt has grown
faster than gross domestic product (GDP) since 2012
1. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System (2019), Financial Stability Report (Washington:
Board of Governors, May), https://www.federalreserve.gov/
publications/2019-may-nancial-stability-report-purpose.htm.
Developments Related to Financial Stability
(continued)
5
10
15
20
25
30
Ratio
2019201420092004199919941989
A. Forward price-to-earnings ratio of S&P 500 rms
Monthly
+
Historical median
N
OTE: Aggregate forward price-to-earnings ratio of S&P 500 rms.
Data are based on expected earnings for 12 months ahead and extend
through June 2019. The plus sign shows daily data corresponding to July
1, 2019.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations using Renitiv
(formerly Thomson Reuters), IBES Estimates.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 25
funding is near its historical lows. Although assets
under management at prime money market funds—
which are more susceptible to runs than government
funds—have increased since the U.S. Securities and
Exchange Commission (SEC) reforms went into place
in 2016, they remain well below their pre-reform
levels. Holdings of U.S. corporate bonds by mutual
funds increased substantially over the past decade,
raising concerns about the mismatch between daily
redemptions allowed by these funds and the time
required to sell their assets. Rules adopted in 2016 by
the SEC to strengthen mutual funds’ and exchange-
traded funds’ liquidity risk management have started
going into effect in the past year.
2
Downside risks to U.S. nancial stability from
abroad remain moderate, but several near-term risk
events could generate meaningful spillovers to the
United States. Two prominent European risks are a
“no deal” Brexit, which remains a possible outcome
later in the year, and Italian scal challenges. Also,
an escalation of the trade tensions between the
United States and its major trading partners, along
with nancial market reactions, could exacerbate
uncertainty and increase the downside risk to global
economic activity. In China, high levels of nonnancial-
sector debt expose the nancial sector to a slowdown
in economic growth. The effects of any of these events
on global nancial markets could be amplied if they
deepen the stresses in already vulnerable emerging
market economies. These dynamics could tighten
nancial conditions in the United States and negatively
affect the creditworthiness of U.S. rms.
The countercyclical capital buffer (CCyB) is a
macroprudential tool that the Federal Reserve can use
to increase the resilience of the nancial system by
raising capital requirements on internationally active
banking organizations when nancial vulnerabilities
are meaningfully above normal. On March6, 2019, the
Board voted to maintain the CCyB at 0percent.
2. See Securities and Exchange Commission (2016),
“Investment Company Liquidity Risk Management Programs,
nal rule, 17 C.F.R. pts. 210, 270, and 274, October 13,
https://www.sec.gov/rules/nal/2016/33-10233.pdf.
assets at the largest banks has remained largely stable
over the past few years. Results of the annual Dodd-
Frank Act Stress Tests, released on June21, 2019,
indicate that participating banks are sufciently resilient
to continue lending to creditworthy borrowers even
in a severe macroeconomic scenario. The exposure
of banks to nonbank nancial institutions—such as
nance companies, asset managers, securitization
vehicles, and mortgage real estate investment trusts—
continued to increase in the rst quarter of 2019. Some
of those rms are signicant business lenders, adding
to banks’ exposure to elevated losses in the corporate
sector. Leverage of broker-dealers increased slightly in
2018 but remains near historically low levels. Leverage
has also stayed low at life insurance companies and at
property and casualty insurance rms. At hedge funds,
leverage increased in the rst quarter of 2019 to levels
slightly below its 2018 peak.
Vulnerabilities stemming from liquidity and maturity
mismatches remain low. Banks hold large quantities of
liquid assets, and their reliance on short-term wholesale
Household
.45
.50
.55
.60
.65
.70
.75
Ratio
.3
.4
.5
.6
.7
.8
.9
1.0
1.1
2019201520112007200319991995199119871983
Ratio
B. Business- and household-sector credit-to-GDP ratio
Business
NOTE: Data are quarterly. The shaded bars indicate periods of
business recession as dened by the National Bureau of Economic
Research. GDP is gross domestic product.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financial
Accounts of the United States”; Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver
Analytics, national income and product accounts, Table 1.1.5: Gross
Domestic Product; Board sta calculations.
26 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
Percent, annual rate
20192018201720162015
38. Real gross domestic product growth in selected
advanced foreign economies
Q1
S
OURCE: For the United Kingdom, Oce for National Statistics; for
Japan, Cabinet Oce, Government of Japan; for the euro area, Eurostat;
for Canada, Statistics Canada; all via Haver Analytics.
United Kingdom
Japan
Euro area
Canada
half of 2018. By contrast, consumer loan
growth accelerated since the beginning of the
year. In the rst quarter of 2019, the pace of
total bank credit expansion was about in line
with that of nominal GDP, leaving the ratio of
total commercial bank credit to current-dollar
GDP little changed relative to last December
(gure36). Overall, measures of bank
protability remained solid in the rst quarter
of 2019, supported by wider net interest
margins and steady loan growth (gure37).
International Developments
Advanced foreign economies have been
slowly emerging from the recent soft
patch
After a signicant slowdown in the second
half of last year, growth picked up in many
advanced foreign economies (AFEs) at the
start of 2019, but at a still restrained pace
(gure38). Notwithstanding continued
weakness in the manufacturing sector and
softening external demand, domestic demand
in the AFEs generally improved amid rising
employment and wages as well as easier
nancial conditions. The pickup in growth
also reected temporary factors. Economic
activity in the euro area was boosted by the
fading eects of car production disruptions
in Germany and protests in France in 2018.
Growth in the United Kingdom surged as
expectations of trade disruptions surrounding
the original date of the United Kingdom’s
exit from the European Union, or Brexit,
led to stockpiling by households and rms.
Economic activity in Canada, by contrast,
remained depressed by oil production cuts, but
recent indicators point to a rebound in growth
in the second quarter.
Core ination remained low in advanced
foreign economies
The rebound in energy prices earlier in the year
pushed up consumer price ination in many
AFEs (gure39). However, despite further
55
60
65
70
75
Percent
20192017201520132011200920072005
36. Ratio of total commercial bank credit to nominal
gross domestic product
Quarterly
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.8, “Assets and
Liabilities of Commercial Banks in the United States”; Bureau of
Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Return on assets
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
Percent, annual rate
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
20192017201520132011200920072005
37. Protability of bank holding companies
Percent, annual rate
Return on equity
N
OTE: The data are quarterly and are seasonally adjusted.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR Y-9C, Consolidated
Financial Statements for Bank Holding Companies.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 27
improvement in labor market conditions,
inationary pressures remained contained,
with core ination readings notably muted in
the euro area and Japan. In Canada and the
United Kingdom, by contrast, core ination
rates moved close to 2percent.
AFE central banks took a more
accommodative policy stance
With activity only slowly picking up and core
ination persistently low, European Central
Bank (ECB) communications took a more
accommodative tone. In March, the ECB
indicated that it would keep its policy rate in
negative territory through at least the middle
of next year and rolled out a new round of
loans for euro-area banks to reduce the risk
of renewed funding pressures. In June, ECB
President Mario Draghi added that the ECB
would introduce new stimulus measures if
the economic outlook did not improve. The
Bank of Canada and Bank of England
signaled more-gradual increases in interest
rates, given a moderation in the pace of global
economic activity. The Reserve Bank of
Australia in June and July cut its policy rate
in response to below-target ination and weak
economic growth.
Central banks’ more accommodative
policy stances supported AFE asset prices
The more accommodative policy stance in
major AFEs contributed to an overall easing
of nancial conditions in the rst half of the
year. Market-implied paths of policy rates
and long-term interest rates on sovereign
bonds have generally fallen sharply, as in
the United States (gure40). Broad stock
market indexes across AFEs are up, on net,
since January (gure41). However, concerns
about global growth and rising trade tensions
weighed on risky asset prices over the course
of May and June. Sovereign bond spreads in
Italy uctuated amid uncertainty about the
country’s scal outlook.
United Kingdom
Japan
Euro area
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
12-month percent change
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
39. Consumer price ination in selected advanced
foreign economies
Monthly
Canada
N
OTE: The data for the euro area incorporate the ash estimate for
June 2019.
S
OURCE: For the United Kingdom, Oce for National Statistics; for
Japan, Ministry of International Aairs and Communications; for the
euro area, Statistical Oce of the European Communities; for Canada,
Statistics Canada; all via Haver Analytics.
United Kingdom
Japan
Germany
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Percent
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
40. Nominal 10-year government bond yields in
selected advanced economies
Weekly
United States
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily benchmark yields. The
weekly data begin on Thursdays and extend through July 1, 2019.
S
OURCE: Bloomberg.
United Kingdom
Euro area
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
Week ending January 9, 2015 = 100
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
41. Equity indexes for selected foreign economies
Weekly
Japan
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data. The weekly data
begin on Thursdays and extend through July 1, 2019.
S
OURCE: For euro area, DJ Euro Stoxx Index; for Japan, TOPIX
Stock Index; for United Kingdom, FTSE 100 Stock Index; all via
Bloomberg.
28 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Economic activity in emerging Asia
struggled to gain a solid footing
In China, real GDP growth picked up in the
rst quarter, supported in part by scal and
monetary policy measures that targeted smaller
businesses and infrastructure spending, as well
as by the more favorable nancial conditions
amid investor optimism on a U.S.–China trade
deal (gure42). Recent activity indicators,
however, suggest that the underlying
momentum in the economy remains relatively
subdued against the backdrop of reemerging
trade tensions, global weakness in trade and
manufacturing, and the Chinese authorities’
continued caution about providing substantial
further credit stimulus. Amid moderating
global trade and activity, real GDP growth
in other Asian economies in the rst quarter
generally remained below their 2018 pace, with
growth in Korea turning negative (see the box
“The Persistent Slowdown in Global Trade
and Manufacturing”).
Latin American economies continued to
underperform
In Mexico, real GDP contracted in the rst
quarter following generally weak performance
in the past two years. Tighter scal policy
and disruptions from labor unrest weighed
on activity amid a backdrop of softening
U.S. manufacturing demand and persistent
declines in petroleum production. Recent
indicators suggest some improvement in
the second quarter, although uncertainty
regarding trade relations with the United
States appears to have increased. In Brazil,
real GDP also contracted in the rst quarter,
as a mining disaster and ongoing weakness in
the Argentine economy weighed on Brazilian
economic activity. Investment continued to
decline, held down by uncertainty over whether
Brazil’s government would enact major scal
and other economic reforms.
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Percent, annual rate
20192018201720162015
42. Real gross domestic product growth in selected
emerging market economies
Q1
N
OTE: The data for China are seasonally adjusted by Board sta. The
data for Korea, Mexico, and Brazil are seasonally adjusted by their
respective government agencies.
S
OURCE: For China, China National Bureau of Statistics; for Korea,
Bank of Korea; for Mexico, Instituto Nacional de Estadistica y
Geograa; for Brazil, Instituto Brasileiro de Geograa e Estatistica; all
via Haver Analytics.
China
Korea
Mexico
Brazil
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 29
Financial conditions in many emerging
market economies improved, on net,
despite the reemergence of trade tensions
Financial conditions in many emerging market
economies (EMEs) eased earlier in the year
in response to the more accommodative
policy stance of the Federal Reserve and
major AFE central banks. However, in
recent months, political uncertainties in
some EMEs and renewed trade tensions
between the United States and major trading
partners have weighed on EME asset prices.
On net, broad measures of EME sovereign
bond spreads over U.S. Treasury rates are
down a little, while benchmark EME equity
indexes are a bit higher since the beginning
of the year. Flows to dedicated EME mutual
funds increased earlier in the year but turned
negative in the second quarter (gure43).
While deteriorations in asset prices and capital
ows have been sizable for some economies,
particularly Turkey and Argentina, broad
indicators of nancial stress in EMEs are
below those seen during other periods of
signicant stress in recent years.
The dollar depreciated a little
Over the rst half of the year, the foreign
exchange value of the U.S. dollar uctuated
but was, on net, a little lower (gure44).
Increased investor optimism about prospects
for trade negotiations early this year as well
as downward-revised expectations for U.S.
interest rates led to a depreciation of the
dollar. But the more accommodative tone of
communications from major foreign central
banks and safe-haven ows—in part in
response to trade tensions and concerns about
global growth—helped push the dollar up.
In addition, the Chinese renminbi has come
under some downward pressure since trade
tensions escalated in recent months.
EMBI+ (left axis)
60
40
20
+
_
0
20
40
60
Billions of dollars
200
250
300
350
400
450
500
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
43. Emerging market mutual fund ows and spreads
Basis points
NOTE: The bond and equity fund ows data are quarterly sums of
weekly data from January 1, 2015, to June 26, 2019. The fund ows data
exclude funds located in China. The J.P. Morgan Emerging Markets
Bond Index Plus (EMBI+) data are weekly averages of daily data. The
weekly data begin on Thursdays and extend through June 28, 2019.
S
OURCE: For bond and equity fund ows, EPFR Global; for EMBI+,
J.P. Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Index Plus via Bloomberg.
Bond fund ows (right axis)
Equity fund ows (right axis)
Chinese renminbi
British pound
Broad dollar
90
100
110
120
130
140
Week ending January 9, 2015 = 100
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
44. U.S. dollar exchange rate indexes
Weekly
Dollar appreciation
Euro
N
OTE: The data, which are in foreign currency units per dollar, are
weekly averages of daily data. The weekly data begin on Thursdays and
extend through July 1, 2019. As indicated by the arrow, increases in the
data represent U.S. dollar appreciation, and decreases represent U.S
.
dollar depreciation.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.10, “Foreign
Exchange Rates.”
30 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
of higher tariffs imposed by foreign countries as well,
these estimates suggest that the overall direct effects of
higher tariffs on global trade ows are, to date, likely
to be material but modest relative to the observed step-
down from 5.7percent growth in 2017 to 1.5percent
growth in 2018.
In addition to the direct effect of the tariffs, however,
rising uncertainty about the prospects for trade policy
may also be weighing on trade and manufacturing.
Measures of trade policy uncertainty spiked last
year, largely reecting concerns about current and
prospective tariff hikes along with renegotiations of
trade agreements (gure B). Higher uncertainty may
lead businesses to delay investment purchases as they
wait for the policy uncertainties to be resolved. Indeed,
Terms of Trade: The J-Curve?” American Economic Review,
vol.84 (March), pp. 84–103.
After expanding briskly in 2017, the growth of
global goods trade and manufacturing, as indicated
by industrial production, has slowed signicantly
(gure A). Even so, other aspects of economic activity,
importantly services, have held up. A number of factors
are likely contributing to the recent slowdown in trade
and manufacturing growth, and disentangling them
is difcult. First, new tariffs appear to have lowered
imports and exports in the United States and else where,
while uncertainty surrounding trade policy could be
leading rms to delay investment decisions and reduce
capital expenditures. Second, a downturn in global
sales for technology goods has restrained trade and
manufacturing activity, especially in emerging Asia.
Finally, a general slowdown in global demand, reecting
idiosyncratic factors specic to different economies, has
likely weighed on demand for traded goods.
Regarding the rst of these factors, global trade
tensions have risen sharply since early 2018, fueled by
both higher tariffs and uncertainty about the prospects
for future trade policy. The United States has increased
tariffs on over $250 billion in imports by an average of
nearly 25percentage points, and U.S. trading partners
have retaliated. Several studies indicate that most of
the cost of these higher tariffs has been passed through
to U.S. importers.
1
If we assume a commonly used
elasticity of1.5 for the response of imports to changes
in prices, it implies that tariffs may have lowered U.S.
imports by about $70 billion, or about 0.5 percent of
world goods imports.
2
Taking into account the effect
1. For two recent working papers that analyze the effects
of the tariff changes on trade volumes and import prices,
see Mary Amiti, Stephen J. Redding, and David E. Weinstein
(2019), “The Impact of the 2018 Trade War on U.S. Prices
and Welfare,” CEPR Discussion Paper DP13564 (London:
Centre for Economic Policy Research, March), https://cepr.
org/sites/default/les/news/FreeDP_Mar05.pdf; and Pablo D.
Fajgelbaum, Pinelopi K. Goldberg, Patrick J. Kennedy, and
Amit K. Khandelwal (2019), “The Return to Protectionism,
NBER Working Paper Series 25638 (Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research, March).
2. See David K. Backus, Patrick J. Kehoe, and Finn E.
Kydland (1994), “Dynamics of the Trade Balance and the
The Persistent Slowdown in Global Trade and Manufacturing
(continued)
Global IP
G-20 GDP
20
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
Percent change from year earlier
2019201720152013201120092007200520032001
A. Change in global trade, industrial production,
and GDP
Quarterly
Global imports
N
OTE: Imports and industrial production (IP) are quarterly averages
of monthly data. G-20 GDP is seasonally adjusted gross domestic
product (GDP) volume estimates at 2010 purchasing power parities
(PPPs) for the Group of 20 economies.
S
OURCE: Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis via Haver
Analytics; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,
OECD.Stat.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 31
investment spending growth has slowed in many areas
of the global economy since 2017. Although this
slowdown may reect a number of factors, concerns
about trade policy have been agged in many recent
surveys of business attitudes and intentions, including
the Beige Book.
The global tech cycle—a synchronized pattern of
production and trade in electronics and software across
economies—has also contributed to the decline in
global trade and manufacturing growth. This cycle is
particularly important for emerging Asia, where about
one-third of exports are technology related. Global
semiconductor sales surged in 2017 but fell sharply in
the last months of 2018 (gure C). The fall in large part
reected a contraction in demand in China, particularly
evident in mobile phone purchases. Recent data,
however, suggest that this cycle may have bottomed
out, as Chinese mobile phone production picked up in
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
Index
2019201820172016201520142013
B. Trade policy uncertainty
Monthly
NOTE: The data extend through June 2019. At an index value of 100,
1 percent of news articles contain references to trade policy uncertainty.
S
OURCE:Dario Caldara, Matteo Iacoviello, Patrick Molligo, Andrea
Prestipino, and Andrea Rao (2019), “The Economic Eects of Trade
Policy Uncertainty,” manuscript presented at the 91st meeting of the
Carnegie-Rochester-NYU Conference on Public Policy, held at New
York University, New York, April 12–13.
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
Billions of dollars
201920172015201320112009
C. Global semiconductor sales
Monthly
NOTE: The semiconductor data are 3-month moving averages.
S
OURCE: Semiconductor Industry Association via Haver Analytics.
April along with exports of electronics in emerging Asia
through May.
Finally, a regular feature of the data is that trade
and manufacturing production move with overall gross
domestic product (GDP) growth but with considerably
more cyclical volatility (a pattern that can be seen in
gureA). Trade and manufacturing production largely
consist of durable goods, the purchase of which tends
to be especially sensitive to economic conditions.
Thus, although global trade and manufacturing slowed
much more sharply than GDP last year, part of their
sharp slowing likely just reected a response to a more
general slowing in global economic growth. A number
of factors have contributed to the step-down in global
activity. A deleveraging campaign by China’s authorities
was an important factor in the slowdown of the Chinese
economy. Growth in Europe has been restrained by
complications with meeting tighter emissions standards
for new motor vehicles in Germany, protests in France,
and the ongoing uncertainties associated with Brexit.
And nancial stresses have weighed on some emerging
market economies, especially Argentina and Turkey.
33
The FOMC maintained its target range for
the federal funds rate
From late 2015 through the end of 2018, the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
gradually increased its target range for the
federal funds rate as the economy continued
to make progress toward the Committee’s
congressionally mandated objectives of
maximum employment and price stability.
In its meetings over the rst half of 2019,
the Committee judged that the stance of
monetary policy was appropriate to achieve
its dual mandate, and it decided to maintain
the target range for the federal funds rate at
2¼ to 2½percent (gure45). These decisions
reected incoming information showing the
solid fundamentals of the U.S. economy
supporting continued growth and strong
employment.
Looking ahead, the FOMC will act as
appropriate to sustain the expansion,
with a strong labor market and ination
near its 2percent objective
At its meetings since the beginning of the year,
the Committee stated that it continued to view
a sustained expansion of economic activity,
strong labor market conditions, and ination
near the Committee’s symmetric 2percent
objective as the most likely outcomes. For
much of this period, the Committee indicated
that, in light of global economic and nancial
developments and muted ination pressures, it
would be patient as it determines what future
adjustments to the target range for the federal
funds rate may be appropriate to support these
outcomes.
At the June meeting, however, the Committee
noted that uncertainties about the outlook
had increased.
15
Since the beginning of
May, the tenor of incoming information on
economic activity, on balance, has become
somewhat more downbeat, and uncertainties
about the economic outlook have increased.
Growth indicators from around the world
have disappointed, on net, raising concerns
about the strength of the global economy.
Meanwhile, contacts in business and
agriculture have reported heightened concerns
over trade developments. In light of these
uncertainties and muted ination pressures,
15. See the FOMC statement issued after the
June meeting, which is available on the Monetary
Policy portion of the Board’s website at https://www.
federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy.htm.
Part 2
monetary PoLiCy
Target federal funds rate
2-year Treasury rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
45. Selected interest rates
Daily
10-year Treasury rate
N
OTE: The 2-year and 10-year Treasury rates are the constant-maturity yields based on the most actively traded securities.
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury; Federal Reserve Board.
34 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
the Committee indicated that it will act as
appropriate to sustain the expansion, with
a strong labor market and ination near its
objective. The Committee is rmly committed
to its symmetric 2percent ination objective.
In the Committee’s economic projections
released after the June meeting, participants
generally revised down their individual
assessments of the appropriate path for the
policy rate from their assessments at the time
of the March meeting (see Part 3 of this report
for more details).
Future changes in the federal funds rate
will depend on the economic outlook
and risks to the outlook as informed by
incoming data
The FOMC has continued to emphasize
that the actual path of monetary policy will
depend on the evolution of the economic
outlook and risks to the outlook as informed
by incoming data. Specically, in deciding on
the timing and size of future adjustments to
the target range for the federal funds rate, the
Committee will assess realized and expected
economic conditions relative to its objectives
of maximum employment and symmetric
2percent ination. This assessment will take
into account a wide range of information,
including measures of labor market conditions,
indicators of ination pressures and ination
expectations, and readings on nancial and
international developments.
In addition to weighing a wide range of
economic and nancial data and information
received from business contacts and other
informed parties around the country,
policymakers regularly consult prescriptions
for the interest rate arising from various
monetary policy rules. These rule prescriptions
can serve as useful guidelines to the FOMC
in the course of arriving at its policy
decisions. Nonetheless, numerous practical
considerations make clear that the FOMC
cannot mechanically set the policy rate by
following the prescriptions of any specic
rule. The FOMC’s framework for conducting
monetary policy involves a systematic
approach in keeping with key principles of
good monetary policy but allows for more
exibility than is implied by simple policy rules
(see the box “Monetary Policy Rules and Their
Interactions with the Economy”).
Since the beginning of the year, the
FOMC has issued two statements
regarding monetary policy
implementation and balance sheet
normalization
At its January meeting, the Committee
indicated that it intends to continue to
implement monetary policy in a regime in
which the provision of an ample supply of
reserves ensures that control over the level of
the federal funds rate and other short-term
interest rates is exercised primarily through the
setting of the Federal Reserve’s administered
rates, and in which active management of the
supply of reserves is not required.
16
After the
March FOMC meeting, the Committee issued
a statement indicating that it plans to conclude
the reduction of the Federal Reserve’s
securities holdings at the end of September.
17
(The box “Framework for Monetary Policy
Implementation and Normalization of the
Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet” details the
recent decision about policy implementation
and balance sheet normalization.)
The Committee is prepared to adjust
the details for completing balance sheet
normalization in light of economic and
nancial developments, consistent with its
congressionally mandated objectives of
maximum employment and price stability.
16. See the Statement Regarding Monetary Policy
Implementation and Balance Sheet Normalization,
which is available on the Board’s website at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/policy-
normalization.htm.
17. See the Balance Sheet Normalization Principles
and Plans, which can be found on the Board’s website at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/policy-
normalization.htm.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 35
The Federal Reserve’s total assets have
continued to decline from about $4.1trillion
last December to about $3.8trillion at
present, with holdings of Treasury securities
at approximately $2.1trillion and holdings
of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed
securities at approximately $1.5trillion
(gure46).
As the Federal Reserve has continued to
gradually reduce its securities holdings, the
level of reserve balances in the banking system
has declined. In particular, the level of reserve
balances has decreased by about $150billion
since the end of last year and by about
$1.3trillion since its peak in 2014.
18
Meanwhile, interest income on the Federal
Reserve’s securities holdings has continued
to result in sizable remittances to the U.S.
Treasury. Preliminary data indicate that the
Federal Reserve remitted about $27billion in
the rst half of2019.
18. Since the start of the normalization program,
reserve balances have dropped by approximately
$700billion.
The Federal Reserve’s implementation of
monetary policy has continued smoothly
Since the middle of March, the eective
federal funds rate has traded slightly above
the interest rate paid on reserve balances. At
the May meeting, the Federal Reserve made a
third small technical adjustment to lower the
setting of the interest rate on excess reserves
by 5 basis points to a level 15 basis points
below the top of the target range for the
federal funds rate; this adjustment successfully
fostered trading in the federal funds market at
rates well within the FOMC’s target range.*
Overall, rates across money markets were
broadly stable since the beginning of 2019, and
the usage of the overnight reverse repurchase
agreement facility has remained low.
The Federal Reserve has started the
review of its strategic framework for
monetary policy
With labor market conditions close to
maximum employment and ination near
Trillions of dollars
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
46. Federal Reserve assets and liabilities
Weekly
Assets
Liabilities and capital
Other assets
Credit and liquidity
facilities
Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings
Treasury securities held outright
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Deposits of depository institutions
Capital and other liabilities
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
N
OTE: “Credit and liquidity facilities” consists of primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; term auction credit; central bank liquidity swaps;
support
for Maiden Lane, Bear Stearns, and AIG; and other credit facilities, including the Primary Dealer Credit Facility, the Asset-Backed
Commercial
Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility, the Commercial Paper Funding Facility, and the Term Asset-Backed Securities
Loan
Facility. “Other assets” includes unamortized premiums and discounts on securities held outright. “Capital and other liabilities” includes
reverse
repurchase agreements, the U.S. Treasury General Account, and the U.S. Treasury Supplementary Financing Account. The data extend
through June 26, 2019.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Aecting Reserve Balances.”
* On July 8, 2019, the sentence was corrected to replace
“the Committee” with “the Federal Reserve.”
36 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
the Committee’s 2percent objective, the
FOMC judged it an appropriate time for the
Federal Reserve to conduct a public review
of its strategic framework for monetary
policy—including the policy strategy, tools,
and communication practices. The goal of
this assessment is to identify possible ways
to improve the Committee’s current policy
framework in order to ensure that the Federal
Reserve is best positioned going forward to
achieve its statutory mandate of maximum
employment and price stability.
The review includes outreach to and
consultation with a broad range of people and
groups interested in the U.S. economy. The
Federal Reserve System is currently conducting
a series of Fed Listens events around the
country, typically with a town hall format,
to hear perspectives from representatives
of business and industry, labor leaders,
community and economic development
ocials, academics, nonprot organization
executives, and others. Policymakers plan to
report their ndings to the public during the
rst half of 2020.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 37
Monetary Policy Rules and Their Interactions with the Economy
Economists have analyzed many monetary policy
rules, including the well-known Taylor (1993) rule.
Other rules include the “balanced approach” rule, the
“adjusted Taylor (1993)” rule, the “price level” rule, and
the “rst difference” rule (gure A).
3
These policy rules
embody the three key principles of good monetary
policy and take into account estimates of how far the
economy is from the Federal Reserve’s dual-mandate
goals of maximum employment and price stability. Four
of the ve rules include the difference between the rate
of unemployment that is sustainable in the longer run
and the current unemployment rate (the unemployment
rate gap); the rst-difference rule includes the change
in the unemployment gap rather than its level.
4
In
(continued on next page)
Monetary policy rules are mathematical formulas
that relate a policy interest rate, such as the federal
funds rate, to a small number of other economic
variables—typically including the deviation of ination
from its target value and a measure of resource slack in
the economy. The prescriptions for the policy interest
rate from these rules can provide helpful guidance for
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). This
discussion presents ve policy rules—illustrative of the
many rules that have received attention in the research
literature—and provides examples of two ways to
compute historical prescriptions of policy rules. The
two ways differ in terms of whether the implications
of the rule prescriptions feed through to the
macroeconomy and potentially back to the policy rule
prescriptions themselves. The presentation highlights
the uses and limitations of each way for informing the
FOMC’s systematic conduct of monetary policy.
Historical Prescriptions of Policy Rules
The effectiveness of monetary policy is enhanced
when it is well understood by the public.
1
In simple
models of the economy, good economic performance
can be achieved by following a monetary policy rule
that fosters public understanding and that incorporates
key principles of good monetary policy.
2
One such
principle is that monetary policy should respond in a
predictable way to changes in economic conditions.
A second principle is that monetary policy should be
accommodative when ination is below policymakers’
longer-run ination objective and employment is below
its maximum sustainable level; conversely, monetary
policy should be restrictive when the opposite holds. A
third principle is that, to stabilize ination, the policy
rate should be adjusted over time by more than one-for-
one in response to persistent increases or decreases in
ination.
1. For a discussion of how the public’s understanding of
monetary policy matters for the effectiveness of monetary
policy, see Janet L. Yellen (2012), “Revolution and Evolution
in Central Bank Communications,” speech delivered at the
Haas School of Business, University of California at Berkeley,
Berkeley, Calif., November13, https://www.federalreserve.gov/
newsevents/speech/yellen20121113a.htm.
2. For a discussion regarding principles for the conduct
of monetary policy, see Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System (2018), “Monetary Policy Principles and
Practice,” Board of Governors, https://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/monetary-policy-principles-and-practice.htm.
3. The Taylor (1993) rule was suggested in John B. Taylor
(1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,Carnegie-
Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39
(December), pp. 195–214. The balanced-approach rule was
analyzed in John B. Taylor (1999), “A Historical Analysis of
Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy
Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 319–41. The
adjusted Taylor (1993) rule was studied in David Reifschneider
and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low-Ination Era,Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66. A price-level rule
was discussed in Robert E. Hall (1984), “Monetary Strategy
with an Elastic Price Standard,” in Price Stability and Public
Policy, proceedings of a symposium sponsored by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, held in Jackson Hole, Wyo.,
August2–3 (Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City), pp. 137–59, https://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/
sympos/1984/s84.pdf. Finally, the rst-difference rule is
based on a rule suggested by Athanasios Orphanides (2003),
“Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983–1022.
A comprehensive review of policy rules is in John B. Taylor
and John C. Williams (2011), “Simple and Robust Rules for
Monetary Policy,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael
Woodford, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3B
(Amsterdam: North-Holland), pp. 829–59. The same volume
of the Handbook of Monetary Economics also discusses
approaches other than policy rules for deriving policy rate
prescriptions.
4. The Taylor (1993) rule represented slack in resource
utilization using an output gap (the difference between the
current level of real gross domestic product (GDP) and the
level that GDP would be if the economy were operating at
maximum employment, measured in percent of the latter.
The rules in gure A represent slack in resource utilization
using the unemployment gap instead, because that gap better
captures the FOMC’s statutory goal to promote maximum
employment. However, movements in these alternative
measures of resource utilization are highly correlated. For
more information, see the note below gure A.
38 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
standard Taylor (1993) rule after a recession during
which the federal funds rate has fallen to its lower
bound may therefore not provide enough policy
accommodation. To make up for the cumulative
shortfall in accommodation, the adjusted rule
prescribes only a gradual return of the policy rate to
the (positive) levels prescribed by the standard Taylor
(1993) rule after the economy begins to recover.
Similarly, the price-level rule specied in gureA
recognizes that the federal funds rate cannot be
reduced materially below zero. If ination runs below
the 2percent objective during periods when the
price-level rule prescribes setting the federal funds
rate well below zero, the rule will, over time, call for
more accommodation to make up for the past ination
shortfall.
Policymakers regularly examine the historical
prescriptions of different policy rules to help understand
the past stance of monetary policy and to inform their
current policy decisions. The most straightforward
way to compute such prescriptions is to use historical
values for the unemployment rate and ination, as well
addition, four of the ve rules include the difference
between recent ination and the FOMC’s longer-
run objective (2 percent as measured by the annual
change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures (PCE)), while the price-level rule includes
the gap between the level of prices today and the level
of prices that would have been realized if ination had
been constant at 2 percent from a specied starting
year.
5
The price-level rule thereby takes account of the
deviation of ination from the long-run objective in
earlier periods as well as the current period, whereas
the other rules do not make up past misses of the
ination objective.
The adjusted Taylor (1993) rule recognizes that
the federal funds rate cannot be reduced materially
below zero, and that following the prescriptions of the
5. Calculating the prescriptions of the price-level rule
requires selecting a starting year for the price level from
which to cumulate the 2percent annual rate of ination.
Figure B uses 1998 as the starting year. Around that time,
the underlying trend of ination and longer-term ination
expectations stabilized at a level consistent with PCE price
ination being close to 2percent. (continued)
Taylor (1993) rule
93
= + +0.5
(
)
+(
)
= + +0.5
(
)
+2(
)
Taylor (1993) rule, adjusted
93
= {
93
, 0}
= { + +
(
)
+0.5
( ), 0}
=
−1
+0.5
(
)
+
(
)
−(
−4
−4
)
A. Monetary policy rules
Balanced-approach rule
Price-level rule
First-dierence rule
N: R
t
T93
, R
t
BA
, R
t
T93adj
, R
t
PL
, and R
t
FD
represent the values of the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by the Taylor (1993),
balanced-approach, adjusted Taylor (1993), price-level, and rst-dierence rules, respectively.
R
t
denotes the actual nominal federal funds rate for quarter t, π
t
is four-quarter price ination for quarter t, u
t
is the
unemployment rate in quarter t, and r
t
LR
is the level of the neutral real federal funds rate in the longer run that, on average, is
expected to be consistent with sustaining maximum employment and ination at the FOMC’s 2 percent longer-run objective,
π
LR
. In addition, u
t
LR
is the rate of unemployment in the longer run. Z
t
is the cumulative sum of past deviations of the federal
funds rate from the prescriptions of the Taylor (1993) rule when that rule prescribes setting the federal funds rate below zero.
PLgap
t
is the percent deviation of the actual level of prices from a price level that rises 2 percent per year from its level in a
specied starting period.
The Taylor (1993) rule and other policy rules are generally written in terms of the deviation of real output from its full
capacity level. In these equations, the output gap has been replaced with the gap between the rate of unemployment in the
longer run and its actual level (using a relationship known as Okun’s law) in order to represent the rules in terms of the
FOMC’s statutory goals. Historically, movements in the output and unemployment gaps have been highly correlated. Box
note 3 provides references for the policy rules.
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 39
Historical Prescription of the Taylor (1993)
Rule with Feedback
One key consideration in evaluating monetary
policy rules based solely on historical data is that the
policy prescriptions from the rules do not take into
account the fact that the economy would have evolved
differently if the federal funds rate had followed the
alternative paths prescribed by the rules. For example,
if the FOMC had followed a policy rule in the past that
prescribed higher values for the federal funds rate than
actually occurred, the unemployment rate would likely
have been higher and ination lower than they actually
turned out to be. In turn, these different outcomes for
unemployment and ination would have fed back
into the policy rule, resulting in policy prescriptions
that differ from those based on the historical data
and shown in gure B. Proper consideration of these
feedback effects requires using an economic model,
which is a mathematical representation of how
economic activity, ination, the policy interest rate, and
other variables interact over time. With such a model,
one can assess how ination and the unemployment
rate might have evolved if a particular policy rule had
been followed over some historical period in a way that
incorporates these feedback effects. Federal Reserve
staff regularly use models of the U.S. economy to
study how economic outcomes could have differed if
monetary policy had followed various rules.
as estimates of the longer-run value of the interest rate
and the longer-run value of the unemployment rate,
in each policy rule.
6
The policy prescriptions from the
various rules based on this approach provide different
prescriptions for the federal funds rate, as shown in
gure B. Presented in this way, each point on the lines
in the gure is a snapshot of what the policy rules
would have prescribed, given the economic conditions
of that time. Because there is no denitive standard for
favoring one rule over another, consulting a range of
rules is generally preferable to relying on any particular
rule. Although almost all of the simple policy rules
would have called for values for the federal funds rate
that were increasing in recent years, the prescribed
values vary widely across rules.
6. The Taylor (1993), balanced-approach, adjusted Taylor
(1993), and price-level rules all require an estimate of the
neutral interest rate in the longer run. In addition, all of the
rules use an estimate of the rate of unemployment in the
longer run. Both of these objects are determined by structural
features in the economy and are not directly observable.
The box “Complexities of Monetary Policy Rules” in the
July2018 Monetary Policy Report describes the complications
in assessing simple policy rules that arise from uncertainty
about the neutral interest rate in the longer run. See Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2018), Monetary
Policy Report (Washington: Board of Governors, July),
pp.37–41, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
les/20180713_mprfullreport.pdf. The current discussion uses
estimates of these objects from survey data.
First-dierence rule
Price-level rule
Target federal funds rate
Balanced-approach rule
Taylor (1993) rule, adjusted
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent
2019201720152013201120092007200520032001
B. Historical federal funds rate prescriptions from simple policy rules
Quarterly
Taylor (1993) rule
N
OTE: The rules use historical values of ination, the federal funds rate, and the unemployment rate. Ination is measured as the 4-quarter percent
change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) excluding food and energy. Quarterly projections of long-run values for the
federal funds rate and the unemployment rate are derived through interpolations of biannual projections from Blue Chip Economic Indicators. The
long-run value for ination is taken as 2 percent. The target value of the price level is the average level of the price index for PCE excluding food and
energy in 1998 extrapolated at 2 percent per year. The target federal funds rate data extend through 2019:Q2.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Wolters Kluwer, Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
(continued on next page)
40 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
Figure C provides one illustrative example of how
accounting for feedback effects can alter the
prescriptions from a particular rule over a given period.
The gure compares the historical prescriptions of the
Taylor (1993) rule calculated without feedback—as in
the earlier section—with the prescriptions from the
same rule incorporating feedback effects. The rule
prescriptions with feedback effects result from an
empirical simulation of the FRB/US model.
7
The
simulation begins in the rst quarter of 2001, a period
when the prescription of the Taylor (1993) rule without
feedback roughly coincides with the historical value of
the federal funds rate. The three panels in the gure
display the paths for the federal funds rate (top panel),
the unemployment rate (middle panel), and four-quarter
PCE ination (bottom panel). The historical data are
shown by the black lines. The gray dashed line in the
top panel shows the historical prescription of the Taylor
(1993) rule without any feedback, the same as the gray
dashed line shown in gure B, and the blue dashed-
and-dotted line shows the prescriptions with feedback
effects. Because monetary policy affects the economy
only with a delay, the paths of the unemployment rate
and the ination rate are not much different from their
historical values over the rst year of the simulation,
despite the fact that the Taylor (1993) rule calls for
much higher interest rates than actually observed over
that period. By 2002, however, the higher rate path
under the Taylor (1993) rule causes the economy to
slow, resulting in a higher unemployment rate and
lower ination—the blue dashed-and-dotted lines in
the middle and bottom panels of gure C,
respectively—compared with the historical values.
Consequently, the policy rate path in the simulation
diverges from the rate path prescribed when feedback
effects are not included. Indeed, by the middle of 2003,
the value of the federal funds rate is substantially higher
in the calculation without feedback effects than it is in
the FRB/US model simulation that incorporates
feedback from the economy. This difference highlights
7.
FRB/US is a large-scale macroeconomic model developed
by the Board’s staff for forecasting, constructing alternative
scenarios, and evaluating monetary policy strategies. The
model and related information are available on the Board’s
website at https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/us-models-
about.htm. An example of the use of FRB/US for monetary
policy analysis can be found in Janet L. Yellen (2012),
“Perspectives on Monetary Policy,” speech delivered at the
Boston Economic Club Dinner, Boston, June6, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20120606a.htm.
the limitations in assessing policy rules over history if
the prescriptions from the rules are notably different
from the historical policy rate path and the effects of
the prescriptions of such rules for the economy are not
taken into account.
While model simulations can capture the effects of
policy rules on the economy and what those economic
effects imply for the settings of the policy rate, there are
important limitations to such exercises. Each simulation
is tied to a particular economic model, and changes in
the model can change the prescriptions from the given
policy rule. Models are necessarily simplications
of reality, and there is no agreed-upon “best” model
representation of the U.S. economy. Indeed, there is
substantial diversity among the models favored by
economists for this kind of analysis. Finally, in the real
world, the structure of the economy changes over time,
so an economic model used for studying a historical
episode such as the one featured here may not be
relevant for future policy considerations.
Model-based simulations with feedback add an
important dimension to our understanding of the
effects of policy rules. However, it is important to
stress that the usefulness of such rules for obtaining
and communicating current and future policy rate
prescriptions is still limited by a range of practical
considerations, even beyond the concerns about which
specic model to use. Monetary policy rules feature
only a small number of variables and thus exclude
many important indicators that are consulted by
policymakers. The policy rules here, for example, do
not include measures of nancial and credit market
conditions, indicators of consumer and business
sentiment, and data on expectations; these factors
are often very informative for the future course of the
economy. Moreover, simple policy rules do not take
into account possible risks to the economic outlook,
which may justify a policy response over and above
what would be implied by the most likely outcomes for
the economy.
8
8. The box “Monetary Policy Rules and Their Role in
the Federal Reserve’s Policy Process” in the February2018
Monetary Policy Report details the limitations of
monetary policy rules in accounting for a broad set of risk
considerations. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System (2018), Monetary Policy Report (Washington: Board of
Governors, February), pp. 35–38, https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/les/20180223_mprfullreport.pdf.
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 41
Simulation without feedback
Simulation with feedback
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Percent
2006200520042003200220012000
Federal funds rate
Quarterly
Federal funds rate
C. Simple policy rule simulations—Taylor (1993)
Rate of unemployment in the longer run
Simulation with feedback
3
4
5
6
7
Percent
2006200520042003200220012000
Unemployment rate
Quarterly
Unemployment rate
Simulation with feedback
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4-quarter change
2006200520042003200220012000
PCE ination
Quarterly
PCE ination
2% PCE ination
N
OTE: Data start in 2000:Q1 and extend through 2006:Q4.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Wolters Kluwer, Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
42 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
sheet normalization in light of economic and nancial
developments. Moreover, the Committee would
be prepared to use its full range of tools, including
altering the size and composition of its balance sheet,
if future economic conditions were to warrant a more
accommodative monetary policy than can be achieved
solely by reducing the federal funds rate.
Following the March FOMC meeting, the Committee
announced that it intends to conclude the reduction
of its aggregate securities holdings in the System
Open Market Account at the end of September2019.
3
Consistent with its decision at the March FOMC
meeting, the Committee slowed balance sheet runoff
in May by reducing the cap for monthly redemptions
of Treasury securities from $30billion to $15billion
(left panel of gure A). In connection with its intention
to cease balance sheet runoff entirely at the end of
September2019 and consistent with its aim of holding
primarily Treasury securities in the longer run, the
Committee also stated that it intends to continue to
allow its holdings of agency securities to decline.
Therefore, beginning in October2019, principal
payments received from holdings of agency debt and
agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) will be
reinvested in Treasury securities through secondary-
market purchases subject to a maximum amount of
$20billion per month. Purchases of Treasury securities
will initially be conducted across a range of maturities
to roughly match the maturity composition of Treasury
securities outstanding.
4
Any principal payments from
At its meetings in January and March of this year,
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) made
important decisions regarding its framework for
monetary policy implementation and the process of
normalizing the size of its balance sheet. The issues
associated with these decisions have been discussed
over several FOMC meetings and have been part of an
ongoing process of the Committee’s deliberations.
1
After indicating in previous communications that,
in the longer run, the Committee intends to operate
in a regime in which it holds no more securities than
necessary to implement monetary policy efciently and
effectively, the FOMC decided at its January meeting
to continue to implement monetary policy in a regime
with an ample supply of reserves.
2
Such a system,
which has been in place since late 2008, does not
require active management of reserves through frequent
open market operations. Instead, with ample reserves in
the banking system, the federal funds rate is expected to
settle near the rate of interest paid on excess reserves.
This system has proven to be an efcient means of
controlling the policy rate and effectively transmitting
the stance of policy to a wide array of other money
market rates and to broader nancial conditions. In the
statement released after its January meeting, the FOMC
also indicated that it continues to view the target range
for the federal funds rate as its primary tool to adjust the
stance of monetary policy. Nonetheless, the Committee
is prepared to adjust the details of its plans for balance
1. For summaries of these discussions, see the minutes
from the FOMC meetings in November and December of last
year as well as the minutes of this year’s January and March
meetings, which are available on the Board’s website at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm.
2. See the Statement Regarding Monetary Policy
Implementation and Balance Sheet Normalization, which is
available on the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/policy-normalization.htm.
Framework for Monetary Policy Implementation and
Normalization of the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet
3. See the Balance Sheet Normalization Principles and Plans,
which can be found on the Board’s website at https://www.
federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/policy-normalization.htm.
4. Details on the reinvestment of principal payments from
the Federal Reserve’s holdings of agency securities, including
information on the distribution of Treasury purchases, are
available on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s website at
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 43
constant for a while. During this period, reserve
balances will continue to decline gradually as currency
and other nonreserve liabilities increase. Once the
Committee judges that reserve balances have declined
to the level consistent with the efcient and effective
implementation of monetary policy, the FOMC
plans to resume periodic open market operations to
accommodate the normal trend growth in the demand
for the Federal Reserve’s liabilities.
5
agency securities holdings in excess of the monthly
$20billion maximum will continue to be reinvested
into agency MBS (right panel of gure A).
When the process of normalizing the size of the
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet concludes at the
end of September, reserves will likely be somewhat
above the level necessary for an efcient and
effective implementation of monetary policy. If so,
the Committee plans after September to keep the size
of the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings roughly
5. In contrast to the Federal Reserve’s large-scale asset
purchases conducted over recent years, these periodic
technical open market operations would not have any
implication for the stance of monetary policy; rather, such
operations would be aimed at maintaining a level of reserve
balances in the banking system consistent with efcient and
effective policy implementation.
A. Principal payments on SOMA securities
Treasury securities Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Billions of dollars
2020201920182017
Monthly
Monthly cap
Redemptions
Reinvestments
N
OTE
: Reinvestment and redemption amounts of Treasury securities
are projections starting in June 2019. The data extend through
February 2020.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve
Board sta calculations.
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Billions of dollars
2020201920182017
Monthly
Monthly cap
N
OTE: Reinvestment and redemption amounts of agency debt and
mortgage-backed securities are projections starting in June 2019. Starting
in October 2019, principal payments from holdings of agency securities
below $20 billion per month are reinvested into Treasury securities, while
those above are reinvested into agency mortgage-backed securities. The
data extend through February 2020.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board
sta calculations.
Redemptions
Reinvestments into mortgage-backed securities
Reinvestments into Treasury securities
https://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/treasury-reinvestments-
purchases-faq.html. The FOMC will revisit the reinvestment
plan in connection with its deliberations regarding the
longer-run composition of the System Open Market Account
portfolio.
45
In conjunction with the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) meeting held
on June18–19, 2019, meeting participants
submitted their projections of the most likely
outcomes for real gross domestic product
(GDP) growth, the unemployment rate, and
ination for each year from 2019 to 2021
and over the longer run. Each participant’s
projections were based on information
available at the time of the meeting, together
with his or her assessment of appropriate
monetary policy—including a path for the
federal funds rate and its longer-run value—
and assumptions about other factors likely
to aect economic outcomes.
19
The longer-
run projections represent each participant’s
assessment of the value to which each variable
would be expected to converge, over time,
under appropriate monetary policy and in the
absence of further shocks to the economy.
20
Appropriate monetary policy” is dened as
the future path of policy that each participant
deems most likely to foster outcomes for
economic activity and ination that best
satisfy his or her individual interpretation of
the statutory mandate to promote maximum
employment and price stability.
Participants who submitted longer-run
projections generally expected that, under
appropriate monetary policy, growth of real
GDP in 2019 would run at or somewhat above
their individual estimates of its longer-run rate.
Thereafter, almost all participants expected
19. Five members of the Board of Governors were in
oce at the time of the June FOMC meeting.
20. One participant did not submit longer-run
projections for real GDP growth, the unemployment rate,
or the federal funds rate.
real GDP growth to edge down, with the vast
majority of participants projecting growth
in 2021 to be at or below their estimates
of its longer-run rate. All participants who
submitted longer-run projections continued
to expect that the unemployment rate would
run at or below their estimates of its longer-
run level through 2021. Compared with the
Summary of Economic Projections (SEP) from
March2019, most participants revised down
slightly their projections for the unemployment
rate from 2019 through 2021. All participants
marked down somewhat their projections for
2019 for total ination, as measured by the
four-quarter percent change in the price index
for personal consumption expenditures (PCE),
and almost all did so for their projections
for core ination. All participants projected
that ination would increase in 2020 from
2019, and a majority expected another
slight increase in 2021. The vast majority of
participants expected that ination would be
at or slightly above the Committee’s 2percent
objective in 2021. Core PCE price ination was
also projected to increase over the projection
period, rising to 2.0percent in 2021. Table1
and gure1 provide summary statistics for the
projections.
As shown in gure2, about half of
participants expected that the evolution
of the economy, relative to their objectives
of maximum employment and 2percent
ination, would likely warrant keeping the
federal funds rate at its current level through
the end of 2019; the same number projected
that a lower level for the federal funds rate
would be appropriate by year-end. The
medians of participants’ assessments of the
appropriate level of the federal funds rate in
Part 3
summary of eConomiC ProjeCtions
46 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Table 1. Economic projections of Federal Reserve Board members and Federal Reserve Bank presidents, under their
individual assessments of projected appropriate monetary policy, June 2019
Percent
Variable
Median
1
Central tendency
2
Range
3
2019 2020 2021
Longer
run
2019 2020 2021
Longer
run
2019 2020 2021
Longer
run
Change in real GDP .....
2.1 2.0
1.8 1.9
2.0–2.2 1.8–2.2
1.8–2.0 1.8–2.0
2.0–2.4 1.5–2.3
1.5–2.1
1.7–2.1
March projection ..... 2.1 1.9 1.8 1.9 1.9–2.2 1.8–2.0 1.7–2.0 1.8–2.0 1.6–2.4 1.7–2.2 1.5–2.2 1.7–2.2
Unemployment rate .....
3.6 3.7
3.8 4.2
3.6–3.7 3.5–3.9
3.6–4.0 4.0–4.4
3.5–3.8 3.3–4.0
3.3–4.2
3.6–4.5
March projection ..... 3.7 3.8 3.9 4.3 3.6–3.8 3.6–3.9 3.7–4.1 4.1–4.5 3.5–4.0 3.4–4.1 3.4–4.2 4.0–4.6
PCE ination ..........
1.5 1.9
2.0 2.0
1.5–1.6 1.9–2.0
2.0–2.1 2.0
1.4–1.7 1.8–2.1
1.9–2.2
2.0
March projection ..... 1.8 2.0 2.0 2.0 1.8–1.9 2.0–2.1 2.0–2.1 2.0 1.6–2.1 1.9–2.2 2.0–2.2 2.0
Core PCE ination
4
.....
1.8 1.9
2.0
1.7–1.8 1.9–2.0
2.0–2.1
1.4–1.8 1.8–2.1
1.8–2.2
March projection .....
2.0 2.0
2.0
1.9–2.0 2.0–2.1
2.0–2.1
1.8–2.2 1.8–2.2
1.9–2.2
Memo: Projected
appropriate policy path
Federal funds rate .......
2.4 2.1
2.4
2.5
1.9–2.4 1.9–2.4
1.9–2.6
2.5–3.0
1.9–2.6 1.9–3.1
1.9–3.1
2.4–3.3
March projection ..... 2.4 2.6 2.6 2.8 2.4–2.6 2.4–2.9 2.4–2.9 2.5–3.0 2.4–2.9 2.4–3.4 2.4–3.6 2.5–3.5
N: Projections of change in real gross domestic product (GDP) and projections for both measures of ination are percent changes from the fourth quarter of the previous year to
the fourth quarter of the year indicated. PCE ination and core PCE ination are the percentage rates of change in, respectively, the price index for personal consumption expenditures
(PCE) and the price index for PCE excluding food and energy. Projections for the unemployment rate are for the average civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year
indicated. Each participant’s projections are based on his or her assessment of appropriate monetary policy. Longer-run projections represent each participant’s assessment of the rate
to which each variable would be expected to converge under appropriate monetary policy and in the absence of further shocks to the economy. The projections for the federal funds
rate are the value of the midpoint of the projected appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the projected appropriate target level for the federal funds rate at the end of the
specied calendar year or over the longer run. The March projections were made in conjunction with the meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on March19–20, 2019. One
participant did not submit longer-run projections for the change in real GDP, the unemployment rate, or the federal funds rate in conjunction with the March19–20, 2019, meeting, and
one participant did not submit such projections in conjunction with the June18–19, 2019, meeting.
1. For each period, the median is the middle projection when the projections are arranged from lowest to highest. When the number of projections is even, the median is the average
of the two middle projections.
2. The central tendency excludes the three highest and three lowest projections for each variable in each year.
3. The range for a variable in a given year includes all participants’ projections, from lowest to highest, for that variable in that year.
4. Longer-run projections for core PCE ination are not collected.
2020 and 2021 were close to the median of
their assessments of the longer-run federal
funds rate level. Nearly all participants lowered
their projections for the appropriate level of
the federal funds rate, relative to March, at
some point in the forecast period. Although
nearly half of the participants revised their
projections for 2019 to levels 25 basis points
or 50 basis points below the current level, the
median projection for the federal funds rate for
the end of 2019 was unchanged. The medians
for the federal funds rate for 2020 and 2021
were 50basis points and 25 basis points lower
than in March, respectively.
Most participants regarded the uncertainties
around their forecasts for GDP growth, total
ination, and core ination as broadly similar
to the average of the past 20years. About
half of the participants viewed the level of
uncertainty around their unemployment rate
projections as being similar to the average of
the past 20years, and about the same number
viewed uncertainty as higher. Participants’
assessments of risks to their outlooks for
output growth and the unemployment rate
shifted notably relative to their assessments in
March. As a result, most participants viewed
the risks for GDP growth as weighted to the
downside and the risks for the unemployment
rate as weighted to the upside. About half of
participants viewed the risks to ination as
being broadly balanced, with a similar number
viewing ination risks as being weighted to the
downside.
A more complete description of the SEP will
be released with the minutes of the June18–19,
2019, FOMC meeting on July10.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2019 47
Figure 1. Medians, central tendencies, and ranges of economic projections, 2019–21 and over the longer run
Change in real GDP
Percent
1
2
3
Median of projections
Central tendency of projections
Range of projections
Actual
Unemployment rate
Percent
3
4
5
6
7
PCE ination
Percent
1
2
3
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Longer
run
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Longer
run
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Longer
run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to the projections table. The data for the actual
values of the variables are annual.
48 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Percent
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
Figure 2. FOMC participants’ assessments of appropriate monetary policy: Midpoint of target range or target level
for the federal funds rate
2019 2020 2021 Longer run
N: Each shaded circle indicates the value (rounded to the nearest ⅛ percentage point) of an individual participant’s
judgment of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the appropriate target level for the federal
funds rate at the end of the specied calendar year or over the longer run. One participant did not submit longer-run projections
for the federal funds rate.
49
AFE advanced foreign economy
CCyB countercyclical capital buer
DPI disposable personal income
ECB European Central Bank
EME emerging market economy
EPOP employment-to-population ratio
FOMC Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee
FRB/US a large-scale macroeconometric model of the U.S. economy
GDP gross domestic product
IP industrial production
JOLTS Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
LFPR labor force participation rate
MBS mortgage-backed securities
OPEC Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
PCE personal consumption expenditures
SEC U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission
SLOOS Senior Loan Ocer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices
TIPS Treasury Ination-Protected Securities
VIX implied volatility for the S&P 500 index
abbreviations
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EDT
July 5, 2019
Monetary Policy rePort
July 5, 2019